018 018 This paper is a product of the Poverty Global Practice Group. It is part of a larger effort by the World Bank to provide open access to its research and make a contribution to development policy discussions around the world. The author may be contacted at fdenicola@worldbank.org. The Poverty & Equity Global Practice Working Paper Series disseminates the findings of work in progress to encourage the exchange of ideas about development issues. An objective of the series is to get the findings out quickly, even if the presentations are less than fully polished. The papers carry the names of the authors and should be cited accordingly. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this paper are entirely those of the authors. They do not necessarily represent the views of the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development/World Bank and its affiliated organizations, or those of the Executive Directors of the World Bank or the governments they represent. ‒ Poverty & Equity Global Practice Knowledge Management & Learning Team This paper is co-published with the World Bank Policy Research Working Papers. Handling the weather: insurance, savings, and credit in West Africa Francesca de Nicola JEL Classification Codes: G22, O12, O13, O16, Q14 Keyword: Weather insurance, Saving, Credit, Welfare, Investment, Risk 1 Introduction Agricultural income is subject to many risks ranging from weather uncertainty, to pests and diseases. The intensity of these risks is exacerbated in developing countries where on-farm work constitutes the main source of income. In the absence of functioning financial markets, households need to rely on a host of informal strategies, since they cannot shield their consumption from agricultural income shocks through formal financial products. For example, they may run down assets or borrow in bad years. When they choose this road, they may rely on moneylenders who charge high interest rates, or on friends and relatives who however may dispose of insufficient funds. These informal strategies have indeed limited effectiveness even against idiosyncratic shocks (e.g. Townsend (1994), Fafchamps and Lund (2003), Gertler and Gruber (2002)). Farmers are in even direr conditions when facing covariant shocks that affect all households nearby and therefore essentially eliminate the networks’ ability of sharing risks. Uninsured income risk affects consumption also indirectly, by discouraging innovation and risk taking. Rare but severe weather shocks may induce farmers to under-invest in high-return, but also high-volatility projects, as shown by theoretical (Fafchamps and Kurosaki (2002)) as well as empirical (Morduch (1990), Dercon (1996), Dercon and Christiaensen (2011), Hill (2009)) work. Reducing investment in projects with higher but more volatile returns has welfare consequences. For example, Walker and Ryan (1990) found that in semiarid areas of India, households sacrifice up to 25% of their average incomes to reduce exposures to shocks. These high welfare cost due to uninsured production risk suggests that farmers could largely benefit from the provision of the right financial instruments.1 In this paper, we examine three formal financial products and assess their impact on investment, consumption, and the consequent welfare implications for rural households in West Africa. Specifically, we study stylized contracts for weather index-insurance, savings and credit accounts, based on the formal financial instruments available for the rural households living in the study area. Each of these products has the potential to improve farmers’ welfare, yet none of them completely abstract from complications that may limit the extent of the gains achievable. Weather index insurance contracts provide new insurance possibilities precluded by traditional indemnity insurance contracts. Under index insurance contracts, the payout is based on an in- dependently observable and verifiable index (such as weather at a local weather station) rather than an on-field assessment of farmer losses. Index insurances overcomes asymmetrical information problems affecting indemnity insurance, and is therefore potentially appealing also to smallholders (Skees, Hazell and Miranda (1999)).2 Index insurance is not however immune from drawbacks, notably basis risk which arises because of the imperfect correlation between the insurance payout and farmers losses (Clarke (2011), de Nicola (Forthcoming)).3 Along with basis risk, also high 1 We examine the effectiveness of selected financial products and acknowledge that other instruments, such as improved irrigation, could be used to mitigate the negative consequences of weather shocks. 2 Adverse selection, moral hazard and costly loss assessment have led developing countries to abandon programs supporting indemnity insurance due to the prohibitively expensive costs for smallholder farmers. 3 Differences in soil composition or exposure, or in the slope of the plots can indeed change the impact of rainfalls insurance premium, liquidity constraints, lack of trust and poor understanding of the product have been identified as determinants of the low take-up of index insurance observed empirically (For e and Yang (2009), Hill, Hoddinott and Kumar (2011), Hill and instance, see Cole et al. (2013), Gin´ Viceisza (2012)). Savings may also allow an individual to better insure against risk, by allowing an individual to create a buffer in good years and draw it down in bad times to cover uninsured losses. Indemnity- insurance and savings act as substitutes under certain conditions (Dionne and Eeckhoudt (1984)). Index-insurance and savings, however, play different roles. Savings can be used to insure farmers against covariant as well as idiosyncratic shocks, while index-insurance offers protection only against the former. However, this benefit may be a very expensive form of insurance against large shocks and an ineffective means of insuring against shocks that occur in quick succession (Deaton and Paxson (1994)). In developing countries, lending to agricultural investments is typically limited by banks’ inabil- ity to manage the excessive volatility of their loan portfolio as farmers’ income is mainly derived from uninsured on-farm work. Banks inflates the cost of borrowing by the probability of default in order to limit their exposure to agricultural shocks. Excusable state-contingent default is therefore e and Yang (2009)). As a result, farmers priced into the cost of the loan contract (Udry (1994), Gin´ are reluctant to borrow and cover the cost of “risky” agricultural inputs, such as fertilizer. Offering a loan with excusable state-contingent default may thus be a means by which access to agricultural finance is increased for smallholder farmers. However, these schemes also have their challenges. Banks are also subject to basis risk and will have to engage in discussions with farmers to explain under which circumstances debt is forgiven. Banks may be concerned that conditional debt forgive- ness will undermine a repayment culture. Although farmers will increase their access to credit and insure lending as a result of this scheme they will not be able to insure their livelihoods. Offering index insurance to banks, rather than farmers, may provide a suitable way to extend lending to agri- cultural investment by curbing banks exposure to production shocks (Miranda and Gonzalez-Vega (2011)). For example, weather index insurance policy will be sold to rural microfinance institutions no-induced excess rainfall in Peru to help offset loan defaults and liquidity problems caused by El Ni˜ (Skees and Collier (2010)).4 We set-up a dynamic stochastic optimization problem of consumption and investment and per- form counterfactual analysis in order to assess the impact of three formal financial risk-management instruments. A key feature of the model is that on-farm investment is subject to multiple sources of risk, both idiosyncratic and covariant in nature, and that a large part of this uncertainty is covariant. This allows us to correctly model the basis risk inherent in some of the financial innova- tions available. We numerically solve the optimization problem using calibrated parameters based on yields, thus preventing the insurer from accurately predicting the losses suffered by households. Similar issues arise for farmers who live farther away and experience different rainfall patterns than those measured by the weather stations. In order to minimize this issue, index insurance can typically be sold only within a limited radius (30-50km) from the weather stations used by the insurer. 4 We model and analyze credit contracts that permit and prohibit the possibility for farmers to default. 2 e and Senegalese on crop model as well as existing evidence in the literature focusing on Burkinab´ farmers. We then show the impact on consumption, investment and welfare from the separate pro- vision of three financial instruments: weather insurance, savings and credit. We start our analysis considering the effects from the provision of the “optimal” contracts (from the farmers’ point of view) and then relax these assumptions and investigate the impact from providing more “realistic” contracts. We recognize the advantages and disadvantages of our empirical strategy. It allows directly comparing the strengths and weaknesses of each financial instrument using a common framework of analysis. We can therefore easily assess the relative welfare implication for the development of the market of each financial product. The caveat is that the results of the simulations depend on the specification of the model. To ensure our results are as realistic as possible we rely on the existing evidence from the literature to guide our theoretical design and empirical calibration. Our results would therefore complement the existing evidence on the behavioral impact of these financial instruments. In recent years, a number of randomized control trials have started to provide information on the effect on consumption and investment from increased access to insurance e and Vickery (2011)), savings (Dupas and Robinson (2013)) and (Karlan et al. (2011), Cole, Gin´ e and Yang (2009)). On one hand, these studies provide clean estimates on insured credit (Gin´ the behavioral consequences of one financial product at the time. On the other hand, we provide a comprehensive analysis of all the instruments within a single framework and complement the behavioral impact with welfare analysis. 2 Model 2.1 Baseline scenario We construct a dynamic model of farmers in developing countries facing aggregate weather risks and idiosyncratic shocks, in order to characterize their consumption and investment decisions and the welfare levels they consequently can achieve. Under the baseline scenario, financial markets are absent and households can rely only on themselves in order to shield consumption against income fluctuations. In each period farmers decide how much of their resources to consume, ci,t , how much to keep in liquid assets, ai,t , and how much to invest in agricultural inputs, ki,t from which they earn farm income. In the following period, they realize their level of wealth, wi,t+1 , which depend on two separate components: the stochastic farm income and the deterministic value of liquid assets. Examples of these riskless and return-free assets would be grains kept in store, or cash kept under the mattress assuming minimal crop losses and inflation rates respectively. Farmers earn farm income according to a Cobb-Douglas production function with decreasing marginal returns. Farm production depends on two factors (agricultural inputs, ki,t and labor li,t ), and it is subject to two kinds of shocks (a covariant shock capturing weather vagaries, ηt+1 , and an idiosyncratic shock representing health shocks, i,t+1 ). Farmers make their optimal investment 3 decisions before knowing the realization of either shock. Income in period t + 1, wi,t+1 is given by wi,t+1 = Ai α 1−α + ai,t , where Ai is an i,t+1 ki,t li,t ηt+1 individual-specific time-invariant productivity coefficient that is log-normally distributed with mean 2 . The distribution of the weather shock, η 1 and variance σA t+1 , and the idiosyncratic shock, i,t+1 , is empirically calibrated from the data as discussed in Section 3. ∞ j Each household maximizes the expected present discounted value of consumption Et j =0 β u(ci,t+j ) −ρ c1 i,t where u(ci,t ) = 1−ρ is a constant relative risk-aversion (CRRA) utility function with a coefficient of relative risk aversion ρ. The optimization problem can thus be written as: V (wi,t ) = max [u(ci,t ) + β Et V (wi,t+1 )] ki,t ,ai,t ≥0 wi,t = ci,t + ai,t + ki,t (1) α 1−α wi,t+1 = Ai i,t+1 ki,t li,t ηt+1 + ai,t The first-order conditions are computed by equating the marginal utility of consumption today to the expected discounted marginal utility of consumption tomorrow: α−1 u (ci,t ) = β Et [u (ci,t+1 )αAi i,t+1 ki,t ηt+1 ] u (ci,t ) = β Et [u (ci,t+1 )] (2) Solving for Equations 2 allows us to derive the finite target level of wealth towards which the household will converge. It equals the level of wealth in the tth period that corresponds to the expected amount in the following period tth + 1, and plays an important role in the analysis, since the calculation of the welfare gains from the different policy interventions are based on it. The scope of the paper is to investigate the impact of the provision of index insurance, savings, and credit on consumption, investment and welfare for farmers. We thus incorporate these financial instruments in our theoretical framework. For clarity, we introduce one element at the time. 2.2 A market for weather insurance First, we assume that a well-functioning market for weather insurance is established. This market for weather insurance allows households to insure against the covariant shock ηt+1 affecting their income from agricultural production. However, as discussed in Section 1, it is unlikely that the weather insurance product will insure households perfectly against ηt+1 , because of these design limitations, not all of the covariant shock will be covered. Two recent papers have furthered our understanding of the nature of demand for index insur- ance (Clarke (2011) and de Nicola (Forthcoming)). Each paper models basis risk differently, but importantly they both treat it as quite different from the additive background risk that is present in traditional models of demand for indemnity insurance in which the uninsured losses are entirely independent of the insured event. In this paper, all non-insured shocks to agricultural production -even health shocks to the labor a household can allocate to crop production- are multiplicative 4 and as such if farmers can purchase only weather insurance, even if it insure perfectly against the covariant source of risk, they would not fully insure. This framework allows us to consider both the design issues associated with the contract and the fact that, however well designed, a contract designed to insure covariant sources of yield risk will not insure farmers against idiosyncratic shocks such as health shocks that constrain the supply of labor to agricultural production in a given season. The take-up and welfare impact of insurance is limited by such design imperfections, but also by these other uninsured sources of non-covariant risk. We denote the insurance design effect as ξt+1 and assume that it is log-normally distributed with mean one and standard deviation, σξ . The idiosyncratic source of risk, i,t+1 , is left entirely uninsured by this insurance product, and this will be another source of basis risk to the household that ultimately would like to insure all the risk to their crop production income. A household can buy multiple units of weather insurance. The actuarially fair price of each 1 unit is given as Pt = 0 (1 − η )f (η )dη since η is distributed between zero and one. Insurance may not be sold at an actuarially fair price, but at some multiple, θ ≥ 1, above its actuarially fair price, in order to cover the costs of marketing the product, and of transferring some risk to international markets. We assume that households decide whether or not to purchase insurance in period t prior to the realization of shocks in period t + 1. However, we assume that household’s pay for the insurance in period t + 1, implicitly granting zero-interest loan to farmers to pay the insurance premium, and allowing farm income in period t + 1 to be used to pay for the insurance. Although this is not typically how index insurance has been marketed in developing countries, this approach reflects how agricultural insurance is sold in a more mature market like the US (Liu and Myers (2012)). The decision problem for the household thus becomes: V (wi,t ) = max [u(ci,t ) + β Et V (wi,t+1 )] kit ,ai,t ,ιi,t ≥0 wi,t = ci,t + ai,t + ki,t (3) α 1−α wi,t+1 = Ai i,t+1 ki,t li,t ηt+1 + ai,t + ιi,t ((1 − ηt+1 )ξt+1 − Pt (1 + θ)) where ιi,t are the number of units of weather insurance the household decides to purchase. If θ and σξ are zero, and farmers can observe the realization of their idiosyncratic productivity before deciding how much insurance to purchase (i.e. if the insurance contract is actuarially fair priced and abstracts from any source of basis risks) farmers are fully insured and optimally set ιi,t = Ai α i,t+1 ki,t . However, it is no longer optimal to be fully insured as soon as one of these three conditions fails to hold, and numerical solutions need to be found in order to determine the optimal amount of weather insurance that a farmer will purchase, ιi,t . 5 2.3 Better savings instruments Second, we introduce the possibility for households to invest in risk-less and interest-earning assets to save income in one period and transfer it to future periods. These assets help households to better smooth income shocks from one period to another, however, they may not protect effectively against large shocks, as anticipated in Section 1. As the work by Dupas and Robinson (2013) shows even though many households may have access to savings accounts that offer a positive rate of return, they may need encouragement to save. We could also think of this intervention as being one that encourages households to save in the interest-earning assets that they may already have access to (such as through labeling, earmarking or social commitments). We modify the model to account for improved savings instruments, by introducing a positive return, Ra , on resources held as riskless assets, ai,t : V (wi,t ) = max [u(ci,t ) + β Et V (wi,t+1 )] ki,t ,ai,t ≥0 wi,t = ci,t + ki,t + ai,t (4) α 1−α wi,t+1 = Ai i,t+1 ki,t li,t ηt+1 + Ra ai,t When deciding the optimal allocation of capital, farmers will balance two contrasting effects. On the one hand, given the assumption of decreasing returns to scale in the production technology, the marginal productivity of capital of agricultural production is inversely proportional to the amount of resources invested, thus at low levels of capital farmers may invest more in agricultural production and less in the safe asset that yields a lower return. On the other hand, farmers want to invest in the safer asset that guarantees a constant return in order to protect their future consumption from the higher income volatility that would derive from investing all their resources in more productive but riskier technology. 2.4 Lending for agricultural investment Finally, we consider the effects of providing access to formal credit for financing capital investments in production. In order to assess the impact of extending credit to farmers we consider two separate scenarios. We initially assume that farmers do not enjoy limited-liability credit contracts, so that their optimization problem corresponds to: V (wi,t ) = max [u(ci,t ) + β Et V (wi,t+1 )] ki,t ,ai,t ,di,t ≥0 wi,t = ci,t + ki,t + ai,t − di,t (5) α 1−α d wi,t+1 = Ai i,t+1 ki,t li,t ηt+1 + ai,t − R di,t where di,t is the amount of loan taken out at the interest rate Rd . Given that Rd > 1, farmer would take out a loan, i.e. di,t > 0, only if they do not hold any liquid asset, ai,t = 0. We realize that this is a rather restrictive credit contract and that in reality banks may offer 6 limited liability contracts. The possibility of default on their debt is indeed one of the reasons why banks are reluctant to lend for agricultural investments. These activities carry large risks and consequently expose to sizeable risks banks’ lending portfolios. When farmers enjoy limited liability contracts, the bank is able to insure their loan portfolio against production shocks experienced by farmers. This default risk is priced into the loan offered by the bank through the interest rate, and is insured by the bank purchasing insurance for the portfolio of agricultural lending products it offers. In particular, we assume that the bank can insure against the same covariant index insurance as the farmer, but at a lower unit price given the larger scale of contract it purchases. The bank however observes the actual realization of the covariant shock only with a certain probability, µ, so that with probability 1 − µ farmers still have to pay back their loan even if they are hit by the worst shock. Once limited liability contracts are offered, farmers’ optimization problem thus becomes: Ai α d i,t+1 ki,t ηt+1 + ai,t − R di,t , ˜t+1 ; if ηt+1 > η wi,t+1 = αη αη µ(Ai i,t+1 ki,t t+1 + ai,t ) + (1 − µ)(Ai i,t+1 ki,t t+1 + ai,t − Rdi,t ), otherwise. ˜t+1 is the extreme weather event that triggers default. The interest rate they pay, Rd where η reflects the higher cost of lending for the bank due to default, that is the interest rate Rd paid by farmers in the absence of limited liability is inflated by the cost of the insurance premium against the shocks that would trigger default. 3 Calibration In this session, we discuss the calibration of each of the model parameters used to numerically solve the model and based on data from Senegal and Burkina Faso. The expected power (CRRA) utility function farmers maximize is characterized by two param- eters: the discount factor β and the coefficient of relative risk aversion ρ. The discount factor is assumed to be the same in Senegal and Burkina Faso and set equal to 0.9.5 The level of β corre- sponds to the inverse of the rate of return on riskless assets (Ra ). The intuition behind this comes from the fact that, in the absence of risk, farmers equate the cost of delaying consumption to the benefit of increasing investment. Risk preferences are typically estimated using laboratory or field experiments or survey ques- e farmers, we can exploit ac- tions. While these data are unfortunately not available for Burkinab´ curate information for Senegalese farmers and assume the same coefficient of relative risk aversion e households. Specifically we rely on Charness and Viceisza (2012) that compare also for Burkinab´ three distinct estimation strategies in order to elicit risk preferences and understand which method yields more reliable estimates.6 Using these replies, through back of the envelope calculations we 5 In the literature, the values of the discount factor β range between 0.76 and 0.99. For example, Zimmerman and Carter (2003) fix the discount factor at 0.95 when studying the saving and portfolio decisions made by farmers under risk and subsistence constraints. 6 ` la Holt and Laury (2002); (2) investment Charness and Viceisza (2012) elicit risk preferences through: (1) lotteries a decisions framed according to Gneezy and Potters (1997); (3) non-incentivized willingness-to-risk responses. Charness 7 derive that the CRRA coefficient corresponds to 1.39, suggesting that farmers are mildly risk averse. Estimates of the CRRA coefficient for African households vary widely in the literature. This is well captured by the different conclusions reached by two recent experimental studies: Harrison, Humphrey and Verschoor (2010) estimate a CRRA of 0.5 while Yesuf and Bluffstone (2009) find a CRRA of 4.2. We rely on Charness and Viceisza (2012) for two reasons. First, their work is fielded in one of the countries in our study, while both Harrison, Humphrey and Verschoor (2010) and Yesuf and Bluffstone (2009) are based on Ethiopian households. Second Charness and Viceisza (2012) analysis compare and select the most reliable estimates, thus minimizing possible measurement error. The production function is assumed to be a Cobb Douglas where labor and capital are the production factors. Since leisure is not included as an argument in the utility function, we assume that farmers entirely allocate their labor endowment to on-farm production. The value of the capital share, α, is set to 0.35 in Burkina Faso and 0.32 in Senegal based on the estimates of the Solow model done by Durlauf, Kourtellos and Minkin (2001) for these countries. We recognize the important role played by the production shocks and calibrate the aggregate weather shocks, ηt , and the idiosyncratic shock, i,t combining evidence from the data and literature. We rely on the crop water satisfaction analysis (CWSA) module to derive the empirical distribution of the weather shock. The CWSA module estimates the impact of rainfall variations on farmers’ yields that combined with the rainfall probability distribution approximate the frequency and size of η .7 The covariant shock takes value between zero and one where zero corresponds to the most disruptive weather shock. The crop model captures shocks due to both excess and lack of rainfall, thus in case of either a devastating drought or flood would be equal to zero. In Figure 1 we plot the empirical distributions of the aggregate shock, η , and shows that farmers in Senegal are exposed to larger variations but farmers in Burkina Faso may suffer from more severe bad weather shocks. The idiosyncratic shock, , is estimated based on the work by Kazianga and Udry (2006). The e farmers can smooth income shocks through live- authors explore the extent to which Burkinab´ stock, grain storage and inter-household transfers. Relevant for this study is their decomposition of volatility of income into aggregate and idiosyncratic components. For both aggregate and id- iosyncratic shocks in each of their six sample village, Kazianga and Udry (2006) estimate the ratio σ µ, where σ is the standard deviation of the shock and µ is the mean of the household income. The standard deviation of the idiosyncratic shocks, σ , used to calibrate is derived by multiplying the and Viceisza (2012) find that the method based on Gneezy and Potters (1997) yields fewer inconsistent answers. 7 The CWSA module is designed by the International Research Institute for Climate and Society at Columbia Uni- versity. It combines soil, crop phenotype, weather databases and management options to simulate crop reaction to water deficit. In particular, regarding weather data, it uses rainfall time series for more than 30 years, and daily evaporation data regarding the amount of soil moisture needed to optimize production. The simulations are based on the FAO estimates for the parameters that regulate crop growth cycle (the crop coefficients KC), its reactivity to water shortage during the different phases of this cycle (the varying yield response factors KY), and its sensitivity to the crops evapotranspiration (Seasonal KY). Finally, the potential sowing window is fixed to be constant across time and the soil water-holding capacity. This latter assumption plays a crucial role in ensuring that the crop model is influenced only by the rainfall distribution and not by other factors, such as farmer’s ability to forecast the beginning of the rainy season, which would be instead captured in the idiosyncratic productivity term. 8 Figure 1: Distribution of the weather shock, η σidiosyncratic µ ratio σaggregate from Kazianga and Udry (2006) by the standard deviation of the aggregate shock µ estimated by the CWSA module. Due to lack of data from Senegal, we apply the same procedure to derive the distribution of the idiosyncratic shock in Senegal. The idiosyncratic shocks in both countries are assumed to be lognormal distributed with mean one and standard deviation equal to σ where σ differ across countries because of the differences in ση .8 In Figure 2 we plot the Senegal Burkina Faso , Senegalese farmers are distribution of the idiosyncratic shocks. Given that ση > ση exposed to (slightly) higher idiosyncratic volatility. Figure 2: Distribution of the idiosyncratic shock, Finally, we discuss the parameters that characterize each financial instrument detailed in Section 2. The premium of the index insurance contract is estimated based on the distribution of the 8 The choice of the functional form relies on the evidence from Claassen and Just (2011). They find a reverse lognormal provides the best distributional fit for US corn yields once county-wide variation is removed. 9 weather shock, η . The final price of each unit of insurance policy is determined by the loading factor. In this study, the loading factor can take three distinct values: −10%, 0%, or +10%. We assume a value for the design effect that arises from the fact that σξ > 0 and the insurance payout are not perfectly correlated with the covariant shock experience by the farmers. Data on the likely magnitude of the design effect is hard to find, so if σξ > 0 we assume that σξ is about 0.15ση so that the correlation between losses and payout is 90%. When we introduce the possibility of savings we set Ra equal to 1.039 (1.04) in Burkina Faso (Senegal) which corresponds to one plus the average deposit interest rate paid by commercial or similar banks for demand, time, or savings deposits since 1990. This return is potentially generous in that, because of inflation, the real interest rate is almost one-tenth of the nominal return, 0.5% in Burkina Faso and 0.8% in Senegal. The interest rate on debt, Rd , is calculated as the average lending rate that usually meets the short- and medium-term financing needs of the private sector. Farmers in Burkina Faso and Senegal pay 16.25% interest rate on each unit they borrow. The interest rate on debt when default is feasible, Rd , is derived by inflating Rd with the insurance premium. The selected values are summarized in Table 1. Table 1: Calibrated Parameters Burkina Faso Senegal Parameters Value Value Risk preferences Discount factor, β 0.9 0.9 CRRA coefficient, ρ 1.39 1.39 Production function Capital share, α 0.35 0.32 Distribution of weather shock, η Empirical distribution from CWSA SD of idiosyncratic shock, σ 0.97ση 0.97ση Weather insurance Loading factor, θ 10% 10% Design effect, correlation(ξ, η ) 90% 90% Savings Interest rate on savings 3.9% 4.0% Credit Interest rate on debt, Rd 16.3% 16.3% Probability of default if hit by the worst covariant shock, µ 90% 90% 4 Results Under the benchmark calibration (Table 1), we solve the “baseline” optimization problem (1) and compute the optimal consumption and investment decisions in the absence of functioning financial 10 markets. We do this for both Burkina Faso and Senegal and find that the level of resources invested in the risk-free asset, at , and in the risky asset, kt , is increasing in wealth, and that farmers invest more in risky farm production as they grow richer. Based on the calibrated parameters, Senegalese farmers face a slightly less-productive but safer e farmers.9 As a result, investment is higher in Burkina Faso than environment than Burkinab´ Senegal, in the case of both risk-free assets and risky on-farm production. Conversely, consumption is higher among farmers in Senegal, at each level of wealth. Starting from these environments, we evaluate the impact of one financial instrument at the time by looking at its impact on wealth, consumption, risky-farm-investment and safe-investment over time. We also study the welfare implications from the provision of each financial products, both across level of wealth (for richer Vs poorer farmers) and over time (for the first generation of farmers that gains access to these new products Vs subsequent farmers’ generations). 4.1 Impact on wealth, consumption and investment We study the effects of offering the best insurance, saving and credit contracts for farmers. The contracts evaluated at the beginning of our analysis are unlikely available options, but they provide a benchmark for the level of welfare gains that may be achieved by investing resources for the development of index insurance and banking markets. Later we relax these assumptions and analyze the behavioral impacts of more “realistic” financial products that can be introduced. In particular, for each product we introduce the most common flaws that are not under the control of policy makers, and discuss the contracts’ details in the relevant subsections. The analysis of each financial product is structured as follows. We solve for the policy functions that capture the optimal consumption and investment choices farmers make at each level of wealth owned. Using the policy functions from the baseline optimization problem 1 we compute the target level of wealth towards which farmers converge.10 We then initialize the impulse response functions at the target level of wealth under the baseline scenario and trace out the wealth, consumption and investment patterns farmers follow to reach the new steady state when one financial product is suddenly and unexpectedly introduced. 4.1.1 Weather insurance First, we assess the impact from providing a weather index insurance contract (Equations 3) that (i) is not affected by basis risk, σξ = 0, and (ii) is sold at the actuarially fair price, θ = 0. A priori, the provision of insurance has an ambiguous impact on investment which can either increase or decrease it depending on the parameter values. On one hand weather shocks deter investment since they create uncertainty in the rate of return. But on the other hand, weather risk can stimulate 9 This is potentially reflected in the labor decisions and value extracted from on-farm work. In Burkina Faso agriculture 90% of the labor force works in agriculture while this percentage drops to 77.5% in Senegal. Consistently, agriculture makes up for 34.4% (15.3%) of GDP in Burkina Faso (Senegal). 10 The target level of wealth equals the level of wealth in the in the tth period that corresponds to the expected amount in the following period tth + 1. 11 investment through a precautionary motive as farmers may find optimal to over-invest in order to have enough income even in the case of negative weather shocks. Depending on the relative strength of these forces, investment can either fall or increase when insurance removes weather risk. Figure 3: Impulse response functions from the provision of weather insurance contracts In order to show which effect prevails we plot the impulse response functions in Figure 3. As soon as weather insurance becomes available in period t farmers increase their consumption, c, as well as their risky on-farm investment, k , but cut their precautionary investment in the riskless asset, a. Next period level of income, w, falls since the increase in consumption is not compensated e and Senegalese farmers follow similar by a sufficiently high increase in risky investment. Burkinab´ pattern, but the higher expected productivity in Burkina Faso allows farmers to enjoy higher consumption. Figure 4: Impulse response functions from the provision of insurance contracts with basis risk We obtain qualitatively similar results, once we introduce more “realistic” weather insurance contracts as indicated in Figure 4. These new weather insurance share a common feature: they are all affected by basis risk, σξ > 0, an element that is unlikely to be eliminated in any empirical project.11 Nonetheless we assume that insurance payout and farmers losses are fairly closely (90%) correlated, in order to understand whether minimal deviations from the optimal contract cause already significant welfare losses. Each contract is differentiated from the other by varying the insurance premium charged, from actuarially fair to actuarially unfair or favorable, that is the loading factor θ takes value +10% or -10%, that is we assume either a surcharge or a discount of 11 Precise estimate of basis risk are hard to find. Based on the limited data available, the estimates of basis risk for index insurance contracts offered range from as high as 75 to 90% (Carter (2012), and Chantarat et al. (2012)), to as low as 16% (Clarke (2011), based on the average level of basis risk present in 31 products actually sold). 12 10% on the actuarially fair premium. Imposing a positive or negative multiple on the insurance premium enables to mimic the potential evolution of the insurance market. A discount on the insurance premium is generally offered during pilot phases in order to encourage take-up among farmers and let them familiarize with the index insurance product that represents a complete novelty in the array of risk-mitigating options used by rural households. As the weather insurance market grows towards maturity, discounts are gradually eliminated and positive multiples are charged in order to cover the administrative costs related to the installation and monitoring of weather stations.12 4.1.2 Savings Second, we introduce the possibility for farmers to access saving accounts so that they can earn positive return on the amount of riskless assets farmers set aside in order to edge risk from one period to the next. Being fungible, such funds can indifferently be used against both covariant and idiosyncratic shocks. As anticipated (Table 1), we initially assume that farmers receive interest payment equivalent to the nominal interest payment made by formal banks in Burkina Faso or Senegal over the past 22 years (Figure 5). Figure 5: Impulse response functions from the provision of saving contracts We later relax this assumption and take into account the presence of inflation and deflation (Figure 6).13 While both countries experience periods of inflation and deflation, the former were much more likely and more intense. As a result the real interest rate on deposit is on average 10 times smaller than the nominal interest rate paid over the time horizon considered (from 1990 to 2012). Farmers increase the investment in the risk-free asset at as the return on investment becomes positive. As expected, they invest more when they can earn the nominal interest payments. The increase in at is financed by reducing the amount of consumption and investment in farm input. The increase in riskless investment more than compensate the contraction in risky investment 12 Empirically we find that estimated loading factors vary between 10% of the actuarially fair premium for area-yield contracts in the United States up to 450% of the actuarially fair premium for some contracts in India. 13 Price growth rates ranged from -21.7% (-28.8%) to +9.7% (+8.8%) in Burkina Faso (Senegal) since 1990. Our framework focuses on the short-run effects of policy interventions, considering only partial equilibrium impacts. Such price volatility indicates that the next step is to fully incorporate the role of price in the analysis. Under the current framework, price fluctuations are captured by shocks (idiosyncratic if markets are assumed to be highly segmented; covariant if farmers are assumed to face the same price). 13 Figure 6: Impulse response functions from the provision of real-saving contract and consequently farmers level of income increases over time allowing farmers to enjoy higher consumption after the initial fall. Results are similar in Burkina Faso and Senegal. 4.1.3 Credit Last, we introduce the possibility to borrow for agricultural investment. Banks are typically reluc- tant to lend for agricultural investment as it would expose their loan portfolio to excessive risks. However, when banks are able to purchase weather insurance for each unit of capital lent they are potentially much more likely to extend loans to farmers. The probability of default is reflected in the increase in a higher interest rate (inflated by the cost of insurance paid for each unit of capital lent), but does not prevent farmers to access credit in the future. Under the more favor- able scenario, we assume farmers can default on their loan with a certain probability µ (Equations 2.4); otherwise, default is not possible. Even in the best case scenario for farmers, default is not always possible as banks and farmers may observe different realization of the worst shocks, this is equivalent to assume that the contract offered to banks is affected by basis risks and that banks transfer this risk to farmers. With or without default, farmers implicitly face an upper bound on the amount of debt they can raise as they need to be able to reimburse the bank even if they are simultaneously hit by the worst idiosyncratic and covariant shock. This upper bound is higher when default is feasible. Figure 7: Impulse response functions from the provision of credit contracts In Figure 7 we plot the impulse response functions when credit is insured. In Figure 8 we plot the impulse response functions when credit is not insured and default is no longer possible. The 14 availability of credit allows farmers to cut the precautionary savings in the zero-return assets, at and redirect their investment to farm production. Farmers become able to slightly increase their level of consumption. The contraction in precautionary savings is particularly pronounced when default is possible. Figure 8: Impulse response functions from the provision of credit contract without the possibility of default 4.2 Impact on welfare Finally, we evaluate the welfare impact from the aforementioned policy interventions. Welfare gains are defined as the permanent increase in consumption that would make farmers without weather insurance equally well off as farmers with weather insurance. Formally, they correspond to the χt ∞ j “baseline” (1 ∞ j “financial product” such that Et j =0 β u(ct+j + χt )) = Et j =0 β u(ct+j ). Given the properties of the CRRA utility function, this expression can be solved by taking the ratio of the respective value 1 V “financial product” (wt ) 1−ρ functions, so that the welfare gains can be expressed as χt = V “baseline” (wt ) − 1. We compute welfare gains across wealth, comparing the value functions at each level of w. Exploiting the dynamic structure of the model, we also compute the welfare gains over time, by comparing the value functions evaluated at the target level of wealth implied by the different financial regimes. In Figure 9 and 10 we plot the welfare gains that can be achieved in Burkina Faso and Senegal respectively. Farmers gain more from the provision of index insurance (Figures 9a, 9b, 10a, 10b). Given the e farmers gain more than their Senegalese counter- longer right tail of the η distribution, Burkinab´ part from the provision of insurance. Subsidizing the insurance premium more than compensate the losses in welfare gains farmers suffer because of basis risk. Even when they have to pay an actuarially unfair premium, across almost all level of wealth, farmers are better off when insurance becomes available rather than when savings or credit becomes possible.14 The welfare gains from savings (credit) are increasing (decreasing) in the level of wealth. Poorer farmers benefit more from borrowing, even at the high Rd , as credit allows them to grow faster towards the optimal level of on-farm investment. Conversely, richer farmers gain more from the possibility to earn a positive return on their riskless assets as, by definition, they own a larger amount of a. The provision of savings leads to welfare gains that are increasing over time. Conversely, the provision of both insurance and credit leads to a decline in overall investment, by relaxing the 14 Extremely poor farmers benefit more from the provision of credit rather than unsubsidized insurance or savings. 15 (a) Across wealth (b) Across wealth (c) Over time (d) Over time Figure 9: Welfare gains for farmers in Burkina Faso from insurance, savings, and credit contracts precautionary motives behind over-investment when financial markets are absent. As a result, the level of welfare gains are declining over time (Figures 9c, 9d, 10c, 10d). The first generation of farmers gains more than the subsequent generations. It is worth noting that the results holds true under the assumption of infinite time horizon which corresponds to embedding full bequest motives. However, as long as future time periods are discounted (β < 1), as realistically one would expect, an increase in consumption today is more beneficial than the same increase at some later point in time. 5 Conclusions Farmers in developing countries face severe uninsured production risks and consequently may largely benefit from the introduction of formal financial instruments that would help them to smooth consumption. In this paper we consider three separate policy intervention and examine their impact on consumption, investment and welfare. We start our analysis from benchmark scenarios and then progressively move towards more realistic policy interventions that incorporate the different limitations that each financial product carries. The provision of weather insurance as well as credit leads to an increase in consumption and a decline in precautionary investment in riskless return-free assets. While qualitatively similar, these choices are quantitatively different as captured by the vast differences in the level of welfare gains that can be achieved. At each level of wealth, weather insurance enables farmers to achieve larger welfare gains which are decreasing in wealth. Over time, farmers gain less and less from the provision of these financial instruments due to the fact that the initial increase in consumption is not 16 (a) Across wealth (b) Across wealth (c) Over time (d) Over time Figure 10: Welfare gains for farmers in Senegal from insurance, savings, and credit contracts compensated by a sufficient increase in on-farm production. As we move away from the benchmark scenarios it becomes clear that welfare gains from weather insurance are highly sensitive to its pricing and that offering a relatively small discount (fee), substantially increases (cut) the benefits achievable by farmers. The introduction of saving accounts on the other hand induces farmers to save more and even- tually allows farmers to consume more. As a result the welfare gains are increasing both in wealth and over time. Richer farmers gain more as they can enjoy higher returns on larger endowments. The initial contraction in consumption combined with the increase in riskless investments leads to higher consumption in the future and consequently larger gains. 17 References Carter, M.R. 2012. “Designed for Development: Next Generation Approaches to Index Insurance for Smallholder Farmers.” ILO/MunichRe Microinsurance Compendium, 2. Chantarat, S., A.G. Mude, C.B. Barrett, and M.R. Carter. 2012. “Designing Index-Based Livestock Insurance for Managing Asset Risk in Northern Kenya.” Journal of Risk and Insurance. Charness, G., and A. Viceisza. 2012. “Comprehension and Risk Elicitation in the Field: Evi- dence from Rural Senegal.” Department of Economics, UC Santa Barbara. Claassen, R., and R.E. Just. 2011. “Heterogeneity and distributional form of farm-level yields.” American journal of agricultural economics, 93(1): 144–160. Clarke, D.J. 2011. “A Theory of Rational Demand for Index Insurance.” Insurance Design for Developing Countries, D. Phil. Thesis, University of Oxford. e, and J. Vickery. 2011. “How Does Risk Management Influence Production Cole, S., X. Gin´ Decisions? Evidence from a Field Experiment.” mimeo. e, J. Tobacman, P. Topalova, R. Townsend, and J. Vickery. 2013. Cole, S., X. Gin´ “Barriers to Household Risk Management: Evidence from India.” American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 5(1): 104–135. Deaton, A., and C. Paxson. 1994. “Intertemporal Choice and Inequality.” Journal of Political Economy, 437–467. de Nicola, F. Forthcoming. “The impact of weather insurance on consumption, investment, and welfare.” Quantitative Economics. Dercon, S. 1996. “Risk, Crop Choice, and Savings: Evidence from Tanzania.” Economic Devel- opment and Cultural Change, 44(3): 485–513. Dercon, S., and L. Christiaensen. 2011. “Consumption risk, technology adoption and poverty traps: evidence from Ethiopia.” Journal of Development Economics, 96(2): 159–173. Dionne, G., and L. Eeckhoudt. 1984. “Insurance and saving: some further results.” Insurance: Mathematics and Economics, 3(2): 101–110. Dupas, P., and J. Robinson. 2013. “Why Dont the Poor Save More? Evidence from Health Savings Experiments.” American Economic Review, 103(4): 1138–1171. Durlauf, S.N., A. Kourtellos, and A. Minkin. 2001. “The local Solow growth model.” Euro- pean Economic Review, 45(4): 928–940. Fafchamps, M., and S. Lund. 2003. “Risk-Sharing Networks in Rural Philippines.” Journal of Development Economics, 71: 261–287. 18 Fafchamps, M., and T. Kurosaki. 2002. “Insurance Market Efficiency and Crop Choices in Pakistan.” Journal of Development Economics, 67(2): 419–453. Gertler, P., and J. Gruber. 2002. “Insuring Consumption Against Illness.” American Economic Review, 92(1): 51–70. e, X., and D. Yang. 2009. “Insurance, Credit, and Technology Adoption: Field experimental Gin´ Evidence from Malawi.” Journal of Development Economics, 89(1): 1–11. Gneezy, U., and J. Potters. 1997. “An experiment on risk taking and evaluation periods.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112(2): 631–645. Harrison, G.W., S.J. Humphrey, and A. Verschoor. 2010. “Choice under uncertainty: evi- dence from Ethiopia, India and Uganda*.” The Economic Journal, 120(543): 80–104. Hill, R.V. 2009. “Using stated preferences and beliefs to identify the impact of risk on poor households.” The Journal of Development Studies, 45(2): 151–171. Hill, R.V, and A. Viceisza. 2012. “A field experiment on the impact of weather shocks and insurance on risky investment.” 2, Springer. Hill, R.V., J. Hoddinott, and N. Kumar. 2011. “Adoption of weather index insurance: Learn- ing from willingness to pay among a panel of households in rural Ethiopia.” IFPRI discussion papers. Holt, C. A, and S. K Laury. 2002. “Risk aversion and incentive effects.” The American Economic Review, 92(5): 1644–1655. Karlan, D., I. Osei-Akoto, R. Osei, and C. Udry. 2011. “Examining underinvestment in agriculture: Measuring returns to capital and insurance.” Mimeo, Yale University. Kazianga, H., and C. Udry. 2006. “Consumption Smoothing? Livestock, Insurance and Drought in Rural Burkina Faso.” Journal of Development Economics, 79(2): 413–446. Liu, Y., and R.J. Myers. 2012. “The dynamics of insurance demand under liquidity constraints and insurer default risk.” International Food Policy Research Institute (IFPRI). Miranda, M.J., and C. Gonzalez-Vega. 2011. “Systemic risk, index insurance, and optimal management of agricultural loan portfolios in developing countries.” American Journal of Agri- cultural Economics, 93(2): 399–406. Morduch, J. 1990. “Risk, Production and Saving: Theory and Evidence from Indian Households.” Harvard University, Manuscript. Skees, J., P.B.R. Hazell, and M. Miranda. 1999. “New approaches to crop yield insurance in developing countries.” EPTD discussion papers. 19 Skees, J.R., and B. Collier. 2010. “New approaches for index insurance.” 2020 Vision Briefs. Townsend, R.M. 1994. “Risk and Insurance in Village India.” Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society, 62(3): 539–591. Udry, C. 1994. “Risk and insurance in a rural credit market: An empirical investigation in northern Nigeria.” The Review of Economic Studies, 61(3): 495–526. Walker, T.S., and J.G. Ryan. 1990. Village and Household Economies in India’s Semi-Arid Tropics. The Johns Hopkins University Press. Baltimore. US. Yesuf, M., and R.A. Bluffstone. 2009. “Poverty, risk aversion, and path dependence in low- income countries: Experimental evidence from Ethiopia.” American Journal of Agricultural Eco- nomics, 91(4): 1022–1037. Zimmerman, F.J., and M.R. Carter. 2003. “Asset Smoothing, Consumption Smoothing and the Reproduction of Inequality under Risk and Subsistence Constraints.” Journal of Development Economics, 71(2): 233–260. 20 Poverty & Equity Global Practice Working Papers (Since July 2014) The Poverty & Equity Global Practice Working Paper Series disseminates the findings of work in progress to encourage the exchange of ideas about development issues. An objective of the series is to get the findings out quickly, even if the presentations are less than fully polished. The papers carry the names of the authors and should be cited accordingly. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this paper are entirely those of the authors. They do not necessarily represent the views of the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development/World Bank and its affiliated organizations, or those of the Executive Directors of the World Bank or the governments they represent. This series is co‐published with the World Bank Policy Research Working Papers (DECOS). It is part of a larger effort by the World Bank to provide open access to its research and contribute to development policy discussions around the world. For the latest paper, visit our GP’s intranet at http://POVERTY. 1 Estimating poverty in the absence of consumption data: the case of Liberia Dabalen, A. L., Graham, E., Himelein, K., Mungai, R., September 2014 2 Female labor participation in the Arab world: some evidence from panel data in Morocco Barry, A. G., Guennouni, J., Verme, P., September 2014 3 Should income inequality be reduced and who should benefit? redistributive preferences in Europe and Central Asia Cojocaru, A., Diagne, M. F., November 2014 4 Rent imputation for welfare measurement: a review of methodologies and empirical findings Balcazar Salazar, C. F., Ceriani, L., Olivieri, S., Ranzani, M., November 2014 5 Can agricultural households farm their way out of poverty? Oseni, G., McGee, K., Dabalen, A., November 2014 6 Durable goods and poverty measurement Amendola, N., Vecchi, G., November 2014 7 Inequality stagnation in Latin America in the aftermath of the global financial crisis Cord, L., Barriga Cabanillas, O., Lucchetti, L., Rodriguez‐Castelan, C., Sousa, L. D., Valderrama, D. December 2014 8 Born with a silver spoon: inequality in educational achievement across the world Balcazar Salazar, C. F., Narayan, A., Tiwari, S., January 2015 Updated on December 2015 by POV GP KL Team | 1 9 Long‐run effects of democracy on income inequality: evidence from repeated cross‐sections Balcazar Salazar,C. F., January 2015 10 Living on the edge: vulnerability to poverty and public transfers in Mexico Ortiz‐Juarez, E., Rodriguez‐Castelan, C., De La Fuente, A., January 2015 11 Moldova: a story of upward economic mobility Davalos, M. E., Meyer, M., January 2015 12 Broken gears: the value added of higher education on teachers' academic achievement Balcazar Salazar, C. F., Nopo, H., January 2015 13 Can we measure resilience? a proposed method and evidence from countries in the Sahel Alfani, F., Dabalen, A. L., Fisker, P., Molini, V., January 2015 14 Vulnerability to malnutrition in the West African Sahel Alfani, F., Dabalen, A. L., Fisker, P., Molini, V., January 2015 15 Economic mobility in Europe and Central Asia: exploring patterns and uncovering puzzles Cancho, C., Davalos, M. E., Demarchi, G., Meyer, M., Sanchez Paramo, C., January 2015 16 Managing risk with insurance and savings: experimental evidence for male and female farm managers in the Sahel Delavallade, C., Dizon, F., Hill, R., Petraud, J. P., el., January 2015 17 Gone with the storm: rainfall shocks and household well‐being in Guatemala Baez, J. E., Lucchetti, L., Genoni, M. E., Salazar, M., January 2015 18 Handling the weather: insurance, savings, and credit in West Africa De Nicola, F., February 2015 19 The distributional impact of fiscal policy in South Africa Inchauste Comboni, M. G., Lustig, N., Maboshe, M., Purfield, C., Woolard, I., March 2015 20 Interviewer effects in subjective survey questions: evidence from Timor‐Leste Himelein, K., March 2015 21 No condition is permanent: middle class in Nigeria in the last decade Corral Rodas, P. A., Molini, V., Oseni, G. O., March 2015 22 An evaluation of the 2014 subsidy reforms in Morocco and a simulation of further reforms Verme, P., El Massnaoui, K., March 2015 Updated on December 2015 by POV GP KL Team | 2 23 The quest for subsidy reforms in Libya Araar, A., Choueiri, N., Verme, P., March 2015 24 The (non‐) effect of violence on education: evidence from the "war on drugs" in Mexico Márquez‐Padilla, F., Pérez‐Arce, F., Rodriguez Castelan, C., April 2015 25 “Missing girls” in the south Caucasus countries: trends, possible causes, and policy options Das Gupta, M., April 2015 26 Measuring inequality from top to bottom Diaz Bazan, T. V., April 2015 27 Are we confusing poverty with preferences? Van Den Boom, B., Halsema, A., Molini, V., April 2015 28 Socioeconomic impact of the crisis in north Mali on displaced people (Available in French) Etang Ndip, A., Hoogeveen, J. G., Lendorfer, J., June 2015 29 Data deprivation: another deprivation to end Serajuddin, U., Uematsu, H., Wieser, C., Yoshida, N., Dabalen, A., April 2015 30 The local socioeconomic effects of gold mining: evidence from Ghana Chuhan-Pole, P., Dabalen, A., Kotsadam, A., Sanoh, A., Tolonen, A.K., April 2015 31 Inequality of outcomes and inequality of opportunity in Tanzania Belghith, N. B. H., Zeufack, A. G., May 2015 32 How unfair is the inequality of wage earnings in Russia? estimates from panel data Tiwari, S., Lara Ibarra, G., Narayan, A., June 2015 33 Fertility transition in Turkey—who is most at risk of deciding against child arrival? Greulich, A., Dasre, A., Inan, C., June 2015 34 The socioeconomic impacts of energy reform in Tunisia: a simulation approach Cuesta Leiva, J. A., El Lahga, A., Lara Ibarra, G., June 2015 35 Energy subsidies reform in Jordan: welfare implications of different scenarios Atamanov, A., Jellema, J. R., Serajuddin, U., June 2015 36 How costly are labor gender gaps? estimates for the Balkans and Turkey Cuberes, D., Teignier, M., June 2015 37 Subjective well‐being across the lifespan in Europe and Central Asia Bauer, J. M., Munoz Boudet, A. M., Levin, V., Nie, P., Sousa‐Poza, A., July 2015 Updated on December 2015 by POV GP KL Team | 3 38 Lower bounds on inequality of opportunity and measurement error Balcazar Salazar, C. F., July 2015 39 A decade of declining earnings inequality in the Russian Federation Posadas, J., Calvo, P. A., Lopez‐Calva, L.‐F., August 2015 40 Gender gap in pay in the Russian Federation: twenty years later, still a concern Atencio, A., Posadas, J., August 2015 41 Job opportunities along the rural‐urban gradation and female labor force participation in India Chatterjee, U., Rama, M. G., Murgai, R., September 2015 42 Multidimensional poverty in Ethiopia: changes in overlapping deprivations Yigezu, B., Ambel, A. A., Mehta, P. A., September 2015 43 Are public libraries improving quality of education? when the provision of public goods is not enough Rodriguez Lesmes, P. A., Valderrama Gonzalez, D., Trujillo, J. D., September 2015 44 Understanding poverty reduction in Sri Lanka: evidence from 2002 to 2012/13 Inchauste Comboni, M. G., Ceriani, L., Olivieri, S. D., October 2015 45 A global count of the extreme poor in 2012: data issues, methodology and initial results Ferreira, F.H.G., Chen, S., Dabalen, A. L., Dikhanov, Y. M., Hamadeh, N., Jolliffe, D. M., Narayan, A., Prydz, E. B., Revenga, A. L., Sangraula, P., Serajuddin, U., Yoshida, N., October 2015 46 Exploring the sources of downward bias in measuring inequality of opportunity Lara Ibarra, G., Martinez Cruz, A. L., October 2015 47 Women’s police stations and domestic violence: evidence from Brazil Perova, E., Reynolds, S., November 2015 48 From demographic dividend to demographic burden? regional trends of population aging in Russia Matytsin, M., Moorty, L. M., Richter, K., November 2015 49 Hub‐periphery development pattern and inclusive growth: case study of Guangdong province Luo, X., Zhu, N., December 2015 50 Unpacking the MPI: a decomposition approach of changes in multidimensional poverty headcounts Rodriguez Castelan, C., Trujillo, J. D., Pérez Pérez, J. E., Valderrama, D., December 2015 51 The poverty effects of market concentration Rodriguez Castelan, C., December 2015 52 Can a small social pension promote labor force participation? evidence from the Colombia Mayor program Pfutze, T., Rodriguez Castelan, C., December 2015 Updated on December 2015 by POV GP KL Team | 4 53 Why so gloomy? perceptions of economic mobility in Europe and Central Asia Davalos, M. E., Cancho, C. A., Sanchez, C., December 2015 54 Tenure security premium in informal housing markets: a spatial hedonic analysis Nakamura, S., December 2015 For the latest and sortable directory, available on the Poverty & Equity GP intranet site. http://POVERTY WWW.WORLDBANK.ORG/POVERTY Updated on December 2015 by POV GP KL Team | 5