WPS6213 Policy Research Working Paper 6213 Demand-Side Financing for Sexual and Reproductive Health Services in Low and Middle-Income Countries A Review of the Evidence Sophie Witter Aparnaa Somanathan The World Bank East Asia and the Pacific Region Human Development Department October 2012 Policy Research Working Paper 6213 Abstract Demand-side financing approaches have been introduced policies. Finally, the paper discusses the preconditions in a number of low and middle-income countries, for effectiveness of demand-side financing schemes and with a particular emphasis on sexual and reproductive the strengths and weaknesses of different approaches. It health. This paper aims to bring together the global also highlights the extent to which results for sexual and evidence on demand-side financing mechanisms, their reproductive health services are likely to be generalizable impact on the delivery of sexual and reproductive health to other types of health care. services, and the conditions under which they have It is clear that some of these policies can produce been effective. The paper begins with a discussion of impressive results, if the preconditions for effectiveness modalities for demand-side financing. It then examines outlined are met. However, relatively few demand-side 13 existing schemes, including cash incentives, vouchers, financing schemes have benefited from robust evaluation. and longer term social protection policies. Based on the Investigation of the impact on financial protection, available literature, it collates evidence of their impact equity, and health outcomes has been limited. Most on utilization of services, access for the poor, financial importantly, cost effectiveness and the relative cost protection, quality of care, and health outcomes. effectiveness of demand-side financing in relation to Evidence on costs and cost-effectiveness are examined, other strategies for achieving similar goals have not been along with analysis of funding and sustainability of assessed. This paper is a product of the Human Development Department, East Asia and the Pacific Region. It is part of a larger effort by the World Bank to provide open access to its research and make a contribution to development policy discussions around the world. Policy Research Working Papers are also posted on the Web at http://econ.worldbank.org. The author may be contacted at asomanathan@worldbank.org. The Policy Research Working Paper Series disseminates the findings of work in progress to encourage the exchange of ideas about development issues. An objective of the series is to get the findings out quickly, even if the presentations are less than fully polished. The papers carry the names of the authors and should be cited accordingly. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this paper are entirely those of the authors. They do not necessarily represent the views of the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development/World Bank and its affiliated organizations, or those of the Executive Directors of the World Bank or the governments they represent. Produced by the Research Support Team Demand-side financing for sexual and reproductive health services in low and middle-income countries: A review of the evidence Sophie Witter a Aparnaa Somanathanb a Research Fellow & FEMHealth Coordinator, Immpact, University of Aberdeeen, AB25 5ZD, UK. Email: s.witter@abdn.ac.uk. Corresponding author. Tel. +44 1943 604413. b Aparnaa Somanathan, World Bank Task Team Leader for the Results Based Financing Knowledge and Learning Grant to the East Asia Pacific Region, The World Bank, 1818 H Street, NW, Washington, DC 20433 USA. Email: asomanathan@worldbank.org. Tel: +1 202 473 1000. Key words: demand-side financing, reproductive health, health financing, demand constraints JEL classification: health, education and welfare Sector Board: HNP Demand-side financing for sexual and reproductive health services in low and middle-income countries: A review of the evidence Introduction In recent years, demand side financing (DSF) mechanisms have been piloted and implemented in the health sector in several countries around the world. They have been attempted in a wide range of settings, from middle-income countries with relatively good governance and strong performance monitoring systems to low-income countries with fragile health systems. Questions remain, however, about their feasibility, effectiveness and sustainability in different contexts. In particular, there is little understanding about the pre-conditions, institutional as well as economic, for their success. The term DSF is used in different ways in different studies (Gupta et al. 2010). We have defined DSF as actions which transfer resources to households on condition that they utilize specific services. There are three possible objectives for this: 1. The first is to change the kind of services which are consumed. Assuming the services are public health goods with external benefits or merit goods, increasing their consumption will increase allocative efficiency in the sector. 2. The second is to improve equity by focusing transfers on specific disadvantaged and under-utilizing groups, increasing their consumption of services. 3. Finally, there can be an objective of promoting choice between suppliers for services, and hence competition, with the aim of improving quality and technical efficiency. The mechanisms through which DSF might work are two-fold – first, incentivizing behavior change (for consumers, but also indirectly for suppliers of services), and second, by increasing the affordability of specific services (as a result of cash transfers or near-cash transfers, such as vouchers). Although the term is used in a variety of ways, it follows from this definition that DSF is distinct from the following (closely related) approaches:  Unconditional cash transfers, which increase income levels of targeted groups and hence affordability of services, but without tying transfers to specific service use  Fee exemption, which increased affordability of specific services, but using a supply-side approach (channeling resources through providers)  Insurance approaches, which can provide protection against health care costs for specific groups, but are not conditional on specific behaviors  Changes to provider payment systems, such as capitation, which may influence consumer choice but cover a wider package of services and use a supply-side payment mechanism Some reviews exist of different DSF modalities, such as conditional cash transfers (Lagarde et al. 2007). This paper aims to bring together existing evidence on all DSF mechanisms in relation to sexual and reproductive health (SHR) in low and middle-income countries. SHR services have been a major focus for DSF, largely driven by concern about Millennium Development Goals targets for maternal health, which continues to pose a global challenge. The paper aims to synthesize evidence on the design and scale of existing schemes, their impact on the delivery of sexual and reproductive health services, and their cost 2 and sustainability. From this we draw policy lessons on different modalities and the conditions under which they have been effective, as well as identifying outstanding research gaps. Research methods This paper is compiled based on a literature review carried out in November-December 2010. Search terms included demand-side financing, or vouchers or cash transfers and reproductive health or sexual health or maternal health or deliveries or obstetric care or family planning or neonatal care or antenatal care or postnatal care or sexually transmitted infections. In addition, we ran individual searches for programs by country or name of program (when known). Google Scholar, PubMed, SSRN, World Bank Imagebank and other library resources were searched. The results reflect some of the better documented schemes – they are not definitive, and there are more recent programs which are either still in pilot phase or not well documented. Much of the existing literature is ‘grey’ – agency reports, which are not yet published in peer-reviewed journals. We have focused on recent interventions relating to sexual and reproductive health. There are a number of studies on vouchers for insecticide-treated bed nets, for example; however, as the main health benefits relate to children, these have not been reported here. Similarly, studies of conditional cash transfer (CCTs) which focus, say on education, but have side-effects in terms of sexual behavior are not included. Older schemes, such as the vouchers for family planning in Korea and Taiwan, China in the 1960-70s, are not described here but can be found in Bellows et al. 2010. Results Modalities for DSF There are three main types of DSF (Walford, 2008): 1. Cash transfers paid when a service is taken up. For these schemes, such as the Safe Delivery Incentive Programme in Nepal (now named Aama), the cash tends to be more limited and is focused on covering service and/or access costs1. 2. Vouchers that can be used to cover all or part of the cost of specified health services, such as for Sexually Transmitted Infection (STI) treatment in Uganda. These near-cash benefits have a similar objective to the first mechanism but can be marketed in different ways (including social marketing and subsidized sale). They often emphasize choice of provider more than direct cash- for-services. 3. Longer term income support linked to take-up of education and health services. These schemes, such as the conditional cash transfers (CCTs) in Latin America, function more as social protection mechanisms. Although there is conditionality linked to specific service uptake, they have a more significant impact on overall household incomes and a wider poverty-alleviation objective. 1 For the main references for the schemes which are analysed in depth, see Table 1. All schemes which have been documented in any detail are included in the tables. 3 Targeting Although it is generally assumed that DSF are targeted to specific income groups, this is not necessarily the case – in Nepal, for example, cash incentives were offered to all women, although with varying sums based on location. In the Janani Suraksha Yojana (JSY) in India, a mix of geographical and income targeting is used. For larger social transfers, such as in Latin America, income targeting is more essential, because of their aim and scale. For voucher schemes, such as the STI treatment vouchers in Nicaragua, specific client profiles can be adopted – this scheme, for example, targeted sex workers and their partners. Fully free or subsidized In terms of benefits to households, the cost of services is usually fully covered by the schemes, but some vouchers are sold at a high subsidy, so that households make a small contribution. As well as reducing costs, DSF also aims to increase their predictability. Demand- versus supply-side financing Although the label of DSF implies that it is an alternative to supply-side (traditional) financing, this is not generally the case. In most schemes, ongoing public financing of services is unchanged, and the DSF component is supplementary or replaces user fees revenues. Payment mechanisms For vouchers and cash-for-services (as opposed to the broader social protection form), the payment mechanism for providers is output-based, with an agreed tariff for each type of service delivered in most cases (though one scheme reports using fee for service payments). Complementary elements In some cases, the DSF is complemented by payments to providers for performance and/or fee exemptions. In the Nepal Aama program, all three components of cash payments to women, incentive payments to health workers, and free delivery care are present. In other cases, the DSF may be complemented by insurance aimed at the poor which covers other services (this is the case in a number of Latin American countries). In the case of vouchers for goods, such as family planning, social marketing of products may run alongside the DSF activities. Organizational context A DSF requires autonomous fund management capacity, which is undertaken in many schemes by a purchasing body, third party organization or external donor. However, this is not necessary, and in some cases the funds are managed by the line ministry. Provider types The providers participating in a DSF scheme can be public, private and private not-for-profit, depending on their availability, capacity, quality and cost in any given context. Scale and scope of DSF There has been a proliferation of DSF in recent years, with many of the schemes focused on SHR. An overview of some of the schemes is given in Table 1. 4 The scale of implementation is very varied – many are national policies, with nationwide implementation, whilst others are more limited, and often supported by external partners. A brief description is given here of some of the main schemes. Cash incentives There are two major national cash incentive programs currently described in the literature, both encouraging facility-based deliveries, in India and Nepal, although other as-yet-undescribed programs are starting in a number of other countries, such as Zambia. In India, the Janani Suraksha Yojana (JSY) program was launched in 2005 to increase institutional delivery among the poor and hence reduce maternal mortality2. It is a nationwide program with central funding, but focussed on the states with low institutional delivery rates. Local associations or health workers are encouraged to identify women and support their access to a full package of pregnancy care, using a birth micro-plan. Cash assistance is available to all women in low-performing states delivering in public institutions or accredited private institutions, and to women over 19 and below the poverty line in higher performing states. Scheduled caste and scheduled tribe women receive support whatever the area in which they live. The tariff of payments is higher for rural than urban areas, to allow for higher transport and lodging costs, and includes an incentive payment to health workers in low-peforming states. The cash is provided by the health institutions, generally at the time of the delivery. The service itself is supposed to be provided without charge in public facilities. For deliveries in private facilities, women receive cash but are not entitled to free delivery services, nor are the health workers eligible for the incentive payments. In low performing states, there is no limitation on the number of births, while in high performing ones, the limit is two live births. Caesarians are carried out free of cost, but where no public facility is available, assistance is provided to fund private care. For poor women who choose to deliver at home, are over 19 and have had fewer than two live births, Rs 500 is made available to support their costs. Some financial support is also given to women who volunteer for sterilization immediately after delivering. In Nepal, the Safe Delivery Incentive Programme (SDIP) was also launched in 2005. The package of financial benefits offered by the SDIP sought to change the behavior of both families and health workers. The level of cash incentive offered to women was set to reflect differences in geographical accessibility to health institutions across regions, covering between a third and a half of the transport cost. Initially, free care was available in districts with a low human development index score. In January 2009, this was extended to all areas of the country, with the new Aama program (which combined fee exemption with the existing cash payments). Since then, a range of DSF has been developed in Nepal, including for ANC, PNC, and uterine prolapse, as well as for PMTCT, multi-drug resistant TB and HIV/AIDS3. At present, women receive $7 in transport payment for deliveries in lowland areas, $14 in the hills and $21 in the mountains. The same payments are made for women undergoing treatment for uterine prolapsed. For women who have completed four 2 This information is taken from the Ministry of Health website. http://mohfw.nic.in/dofw%20website/JSY_features_FAQ_Nov_2006.htm 3 Scoping report for the National Health Sector Support Programme, Witter & Prasai, December 2010 5 or more ANC visits, an additional $2.2 is paid, and there is piloting of payments for those who complete three PNC visits ($4.2). Vouchers Voucher programs are typically implemented on a smaller scale – aimed at specific groups and specific areas, and in all cases with external funding and technical support. Services covered have included maternal health care (ANC, deliveries, PNC), family planning, treatment of STIs and counseling and treatment of gender-based violence. There are currently also two pilots being undertaken in Malawi and South Africa using vouchers for male circumcision (Boler and Harris, 2010). KfW has recently been supporting the use of vouchers for family planning and delivery services in Kenya and Uganda. Vouchers are offered for sale at a highly subsidized rate (200 Shillings per delivery in Kenya – around $2.5). To identify members of the target group, a participatory poverty grading tool was developed for the four targeted Kenyan districts. The tool is district-specific and includes eight indicators (housing, access to medical facility, water source, rent amounts, sanitation, income levels, and number of meals taken per day). A score rate of between 8 and 16 points qualifies the person one to purchase the voucher. Providers are a mix of public, private and NGO-based. Under the World Bank-funded Poverty Action Fund in China, poor households in Yunan province were given MCH vouchers to cover the user fees for specific categories of mother and child health care, including routine pre- and post-natal care, hospital delivery care for high-risk pregnant women; and first aid for severe obstetric complications. The vouchers were collected by facilities and sent to the provincial headquarters for reimbursement. The very poor and poor (14% of the population) were identified through village councils (Kelin, Kaining, & Songuan 2001). Further data on this program has not been identified however. In Bangladesh, a voucher scheme for maternal health care was piloted by UNFPA and WHO. The vouchers were distributed to households below a certain income threshold, entitling them to free deliveries for their first and second pregnancies, subject to adopting family planning. This was later rolled out by the government in 2007 to 33 sub-districts (in some using targeted vouchers and in others universal ones). Under the Maternal Health Voucher Scheme, target women receive vouchers for three ANC check-ups, safe delivery at a facility or at home by skilled birth attendants, a postnatal check-up within 6 weeks of delivery and management of complications including caesarean section from designated providers. They also receive transportation costs for accessing the covered services. Vouchers for maternal health have also been used in some districts of Cambodia, alongside a range of other measures such as health equity funds and contracting of services. There have also been pilot projects in Indonesia and Pakistan, and a longer-standing voucher scheme for private provision of delivery care in Gujurat state, India. In Nicaragua, a voucher scheme has been implemented to increase the prevention and treatment of STIs in high-risk groups, such as sex workers(Sandiford, Gorter, & Salvetto 2002). A reproductive voucher scheme was also supported in Managua in 2000 (Meuwissen, 2006). 6 Social transfers The social transfer approach has been developed extensively in Latin America. The focus of most of the programs has been on child health, educational attendance and, to a lesser extent, preventive care for mothers. Reproductive health is therefore only a small strand within the studies. In recent years, the model has been exported to Asia, with pilots established in Indonesia and the Philippines. The best known example is the PROGRESA program (later Opportunidades) in Mexico, aimed at improving children’s education, health and nutrition through conditional cash transfers. Low-income families were given a subsidy on condition they obtained a range of health services including nutrition monitoring and supplements for children and lactating mothers, growth monitoring for the under-fives, antennal care and child immunizations and attended various adult health promotion clinics (Gertler, 2000). Honduras has operated a family allowance program – a scheme distributing freely exchangeable vouchers through primary schools or the program itself for antenatal (ANC) visits, perinatal checkups, and monthly well-child checkups (Morris, et al. 2004a). This is part of a wider social protection system, providing montly income, and is therefore included under social transfers, despite using a voucher mechanism. Brazil has been operating the ‘Bolsa Alimentacao’, a scheme providing cash payments via magnetic debit cards to be used at automatic teller machines or lottery ticket sellers for antenatal care visits, monthly well-child checkups, immunization and growth monitoring services (Morris, et al. 2004b). Although ANC is included, the focus of this intervention is improving child health. Similarly, Bolivia has a cash transfer scheme, available to all households in 70 rural districts with a pregnant woman or young child, conditional on their use of preventive services (Morris & et al. 2004). Evidence of impact The quality of evidence varies across different projects and policies – some have been subject to fairly rigorous impact evaluations (e.g. the JSY in India and the SDIP in Nepal, as well as the Bangladesh and Nicaragua vouchers schemes, and the social transfers in Mexico and Honduras), while others rely on internal project data or administrative sources to assess impact. A summary of results is given below, but giving more weight to the more robust studies. Utilization of services Raising the utilization of specific services is a core aim of the DSF policies, and this output indicator is reported in all studies (see table 2), though with varying degrees of adjustment for other influencing factors. Unsurprisingly, given the policy mechanisms, all report increased utilization, although the degree of response is sometimes lower than expected, suggesting either low price elasticity of demand, poor implementation of policies and/or the presence of other (non-financial) barriers to service use. 7 Studies often fail to assess the degree to which increases reflect switching by users (e.g. from private to public services). Possible spillover effects on non-targeted groups are also often ignored. Cash incentives A process evaluation found that there was evidence to suggest that institutional deliveries had increased due to the JSY in India (Devadasan et al. 2008). However, it was apparent that there are some weaknesses in the scheme. Women were not aware of the scheme in some states. Changes in the benefits were promoting home deliveries, which conflicted with the original objective of encouraging institutional deliveries to reduce maternal and neonatal deaths. The authors also concluded that documentation procedures had evolved into a cumbersome process and had the potential to deny benefits to the needy. An impact evaluation of the JSY found that implementation was highly variable by state—from less than 5% to 44% of women giving birth receiving cash payments from JSY (Lim et al. 2010). The poorest and least educated women did not always have the highest odds of receiving JSY payments. It found that the JSY had a significant effect on increasing antenatal care and in-facility births. An evaluation report found that implementation of the SDIP in Nepal had been well below the target level of paying all eligible beneficiaries but was showing promising signs of improvement over time (Powell-Jackson et al. 2008). Women exposed to the SDIP were 24 percent more likely to use government health institutions, 5 percent less likely to deliver at home and 13 percent more likely to have a skilled attendant at delivery. However, there was no evidence that the SDIP increased use of life- saving obstetric surgery (caesarean sections). Vouchers All voucher schemes reported increased utilization – for example, an increase of 21% in institutional deliveries was recorded in the first year of implementation of the Chiranjeevi Yojana policy in Gujurat (CYG), India. In the Bangladesh voucher scheme, women living in areas with universal entitlement were found to be 26% more likely to deliver in a health facility, while those in targeted areas were 13% more likely (and no difference with control areas was found for caesarean sections). For the STI vouchers in Uganda, there was a 15% increase in utilization of treatment services in the first two years, but skewed toward those living within 10 km of facilities. A more closely targeted voucher scheme aimed at sex workers and their partners and clients in Managua produced a more dramatic increase in treatment of the four most common STIs – up from 15% before the project to 92% afterwards. For sexual and reproductive health care vouchers distributed to adolescents in Managua, 34% of voucher recipients used these services, compared with 19% of non-receivers, leading to a higher use of modern contraceptives and condoms. However, use of vouchers is sometimes low, especially for delivery care where access and cultural factors play an important role. A recent study of the combined effects of vouchers and health equity funds in some districts of Cambodia concluded that vouchers had increased facility utilization and had brought to facilities pregnant women who had previously delivered at home (Por et al. 2008). However, 8 uptake was disappointing – less than 50% of women who were given vouchers used them for delivery care. Social transfers The social transfers were focused on child health and education services and have had modest reported impact on use of ANC. In the case of the Mexico and Honduras policies, this was one of the conditional services on which receipt of funds depended, so an increase in utilization would certainly be expected, although the degree to which conditionality was monitored and enforced is reported to have varied across schemes (PAHO/WHO 2007). It is also noteworthy that despite its proven importance to mother and child health, none of the Latin American conditional cash transfer schemes included facility deliveries in their conditionality, perhaps because they were covered by health insurance programs for the poor. No difference in antenatal care (ANC) utilization was found in rural areas in the first phase of PROGRESA, though for the second phase in urban areas, ANC increased by 6%. A study focussing on family planning (FP) uptake (Feldman et al. 2009) found that the ‘treatment group’ were more likely to use modern contraception, but had no difference in birth spacing and were no more likely to deliver in a health institution. In Honduras, an increase of 18% in ANC was recorded in a trial related to the policy (Morris et al. 2004). Access to services for the poor For many of the schemes which are targeted at poor households (identified through a variety of criteria and channels), analysis of the distribution of benefits or differential impact on access by different groups has not been conducted, perhaps on the assumption that they can be assumed to be pro-poor. Where analysis has been done, universal schemes have tended to benefit middle-income households disproportionately in the cash incentive schemes. Targeted schemes (where analysis is available) report under-coverage of their target group in some cases (e.g. the CY in Gujurat), while in others there is considerable ‘leakage’ (e.g. 40% o the top two quintiles receiving vouchers in the Honduras BMI, and 49% of women in the top two quintiles in Bangladesh receiving maternal health vouchers). Cash incentives For the JSY in India, implementation has varied considerably across states, but the national evaluation found that women of middle wealth and middle income were most likely to benefit from the scheme (Lim et al 2010). In rural areas, those living close to facilities were more likely to benefit. In relation to equity, the impact of the SDIP in Nepal on utilization of skilled birth attendance was also greatest among women of average wealth (middle wealth quintile) (Powell-Jackson, Neupane, Tiwari, Morrison, & Costello 2008). Women exposed to the SDIP and in the middle wealth quintile were 93 percent more likely to use government delivery care services and 66 percent more likely to use a skilled attendant at delivery. While the impact was slightly less among the poorest two-fifths of women, they were still 64 percent more likely to use a skilled attendant at delivery. In contrast, there was no evidence that the 9 SDIP had any impact on skilled birth attendance among the richest two-fifths of women. For these women, the SDIP simply encouraged them away from NGO or mission health institutions (where available) into government health institutions. Inequality in the use of delivery care services provided by government health facilities means that the recipients of the cash incentive are disproportionately richer households. This is to be expected since there is no specific targeting of poorer households in the SDIP. Among women who were eligible and meant to receive the money, women with no education, unaware of the SDIP, living more than one hour from the health institution and Dalits were less likely to receive the cash. Vouchers Most studies of vouchers schemes do not analyze differential uptake. For the STI voucher scheme in Nicaragua, there was no analysis of coverage of the target group, but the poor and those with more STIs were reported to be more likely to use their vouchers. For the Bangladesh MHV scheme, it contributed to reduced inequity in facility deliveries, but 49% of women in the top two quintiles benefited, even in targeted areas. By contrast, the Gujarat vouchers were well targeted but failed to cover all of the poor. Social transfers Targeting of PROGRESA has been effective: 80% of its beneficiaries were estimated to be in the poorest 40% of the population (Gwatkin, Bhuiya, & Victora 2004), although later studies indicate that this may have dropped to 60%. It is very different in scale compared to many of the other DSF policies, however, covering 40% of rural households. Moreover, its targeting costs are substantial - estimated at 30% of total costs (Gertler 2000). For the Honduras BMI, it is reported to have reached 84% of its target group, but with 40% of beneficiaries in the top two quintiles. Financial protection Reproductive health costs can be significant for households. However, while DSF schemes aim to improve the affordability of specific services, very few evaluation studies examine the impact of the policy on household spending on reproductive services or health care in general. Cash incentives The SDIP evaluation (Powell-Jackson, Neupane, Tiwari, Morrison, & Costello 2008) is an exception: it concludes that the cash incentive protects a small proportion of households from catastrophic expenditure but fails to protect households from being forced into poverty that results from delivery care payments. In one district, Makwanpur, the cash incentive represented less than 20 percent of out- of-pocket expenditure on institutional delivery care, an inadequate amount to reduce the impoverishing effects of these health care payments. In India the JSY scheme covered less than half the costs of women. In addition, around a third of women reported not having received the incentives (Lim et al. 2010). Vouchers In general, vouchers are reported to have reduced user costs for services (unsurprisingly), but the significance of this in relation to household incomes or expenditure is generally not assessed. For the Bangladesh scheme, lower out-of-pocket payments by beneficiaries were recorded; however, only 60- 10 65% of women reported receiving their nutritional cash incentive (the largest component of the cash payments due to them) (Hatt et al. 2010). Social transfers Financial protection is not assessed directly for the social transfers, but the value of the overall transfer is known – around 20% of average household consumption in Mexico, but much lower in Honduras (4%). As services are free, the aim of these transfers is poverty alleviation (with conditionality), rather than financial protection against health care costs per se – at least in the Mexican policy. For Honduras, the lower level transfer might more appropriately be seen as compensation for the opportunity costs of accessing services. Quality of care A number of the studies – in India, Nepal and Bangladesh, for example - highlighted poor quality of care or supply side constraints (such as inadequate staffing and services), before as after the introduction of the DSF schemes (Table 3). Clearly, a DSF approach presupposes that services are available, accessible and able to offer a reasonable quality of care – otherwise higher utilization is likely to be ineffective or even positively dangerous. For that reason, a number of interventions were accompanied by supply-side measures to upgrade services. These included provider incentives, training, and upgrading of facilities in some cases. In only a few cases were checks done to assess the technical quality of care. In the Uganda RH voucher scheme, the proportion of correct treatments was high, especially for the more common STIs. In the Nicaragua STI voucher program, simulated patients were used to assess quality of care, and this demonstrated some improvements following the start of the program (although some indicators dropped again after the program stopped). Improvements in quality of care rely on DSF schemes either increasing consumer choice pressures (where there are alternative providers of reasonable quality available) or the schemes adding significant resources for providers. Where there is choice, accreditation mechanisms can also be used to ensure that only providers of a certain standard are reimbursed under the scheme. However, there often is no effective choice either because providers do not sign up to the scheme because the reimbursement level is insufficient (private providers are often not keen for this reason) or because there is a limited range of providers in a given area. The rapid review of the Bangladesh voucher scheme, for example, found there was little evidence that the mechanism encouraged competition due to the limited provision of health care services (Schmidt et al. 2010). It concluded that the voucher scheme provided substantial additional funding to facilities but remained complex to administer, requiring a parallel administrative mechanism which put an additional work burden on the health workers. Health outcomes Measuring health outcomes gains and attributing them to the DSF intervention is ambitious and many studies (e.g. Nepal, Kenya, Gujarat) do not attempt to do this (see Table 3). In other cases, positive trends are noted but cannot be attributed with confidence to the policy (Bangladesh and Indonesia). For some policies (e.g. Honduras), no health gains were found by evaluators. For some of the policies, improved user knowledge is an important outcome – this is reported, for example, in the Nicaragua STI and SRH voucher programs. In the Nicaragua STI voucher scheme, declines 11 in rates of syphilis and gonorrhea are reported (Sandiford, Gorter et al., 2002), as is also the case for the Ugandan RH vouchers, where a 42% drop in syphilis prevalence was found in the first year (Bellows and Hamilton, 2009). The JSY payment was associated with a reduction of 3.7 in perinatal deaths per 1,000 pregnancies and 2.3 neonatal deaths per 1,000 live births, but no significant impact on maternal mortality could be detected using that sample size (Lim et al. 2010). In Mexico, cash transfers alongside information, micro-nutrient supplementation, weight monitoring etc brought about higher birth weights and improvements in child nutritional status, especially stunting. Costs and cost effectiveness Total costs Total cost information is available for most (8 out of 13) of the policies which are studied in depth (see table 4). The different scales of the DSF policies is illustrated by comparing the size of their budgets, ranging from $60,000 per year to provide vouchers to a specific client group in one city (the Nicaragua STI scheme) to $3.6 billion for the PROGESA/Opportunidades program in Mexico, which enhances the income of an estimated 25% of the country’s population. Cost breakdown Costs are hard to compare, given the different packages being offered. However, the proportion of spending which comprises overhead costs is of interest, as one measure of efficiency (although some overhead costs can be very productive – for example, investments in training of providers or communication to clients can be effective interventions in their own right). Not all studies report overhead costs and classifications vary, but the available information is nevertheless illuminating. For the national JSY policy in India, implemented through the national health system, the overheads are limited to a total of 11%. For Nepal, the proportion is not reported. The proportion is likely to be relatively low; however, implementation difficulties may be a reflection of under-investment in strong administrative systems in both of these cases. Two voucher schemes in neighboring countries – both in their start-up phases – nevertheless had overhead costs of 21% in one case (Kenya) and 72% in the other (Uganda). For voucher schemes, a complicated array of administrative structures is needed for voucher management, accreditation of providers, voucher distribution, setting reimbursement rates and claims processing. These are costly and require developed management capacity (in Kenya, an international management consultancy firm was hired to provide voucher management functions). It is not clear however why there is such a divergence between the two schemes. A systematic review of conditional cash transfers found that the value of the transfers constituted a mere 4% of overall program expenditure for the Mexican scheme, 8% in Nicaragua, 16% in Columbia 12 and 28% in Honduras (Lagaarde, Haines and Palmer, 2007). Targeting, conditioning, and administrative costs are amongst the overhead categories. Cost effectiveness None of the studies examined the cost-effectiveness of their DSF interventions, with the exception of the Nicaraguan STI voucher scheme, which was found to be cost-effective, with a lower cost per STI patient effectively cured costs compared to before ($118 compared to the status quo of $200). Funding and sustainability There is a correlation between the level of development of a country and the funding of their DSF policies – by and large, low income countries have external funding, while for low and upper middle income countries, some or all of the funding comes from local sources. Some policies are quite ambitious: in Mexico, the overall Opportunidades policy absorbs 45% of the entire federal anti-poverty budget (Barber and Gertler, 2008), while in India, almost half of the federal budget for maternal health is now absorbed by the incentive scheme (Walford, 2004). As many of the policies are young, it is hard to assess at this stage their likelihood of being sustained, and indeed it is not yet clear how long they should be maintained in order to meet their objectives. There is a risk that after 2015 many of the policies focused on improving maternal health may lose support. Discussion Preconditions for effectiveness A number of factors for success of these reproductive DSF policies are drawn out here, not necessarily in order of importance. 1. Correct identification of demand-side barriers to use DSF approaches will work best when services are underutilized by the target group for reasons which are predominantly financial. DSF works on the asumption that supply-side subsidies provided by government may not be effective at targeting those in most need. There is strong evidence that the poor have inferior access and make lower use of publicly allocated resources and services (Demery 2000, Institute of Policy Studies 2001, van Doorslaer, et al. 1993). This is for a variety of reasons, however, many of which are non-financial, including poor physical access to facilities, ignorance of treatment options, poor treatment by providers, and other constraints (cultural, gender, ethnic, caste etc.) preventing health seeking behaviour. Where non-financial barriers predominate, alternative policies may be more effective, or complementary actions to address these wider factors are likely to be necessary to make DSF schemes effective. Reproductive health is an area where social and cultural factors tend to play an important role in health seeking choices. The assumption that improving the affordability of the service alone will raise demand does not always hold. In the case of Cambodia, the low utilization of delivery vouchers (which covered the full range of costs, including transport) raised the issue of cultural perceptions and other (non-price) barriers. 13 Interviews with non-users revealed that concerns about finding transport to facilities, about poor staff attitudes in facilities and about taking care of their household were responsible for women not using their vouchers (Por et al. 2010). For the Kenya voucher scheme, a range of marketing strategies had to be developed – what worked in rural was different for urban areas (Bellows et al. 2009). In Pakistan, in addition to distributing vouchers, the project invested in communication activities, meeting with women, and providing testimony from women who had used services to break down cultural barriers. Three to four visits were needed per household to develop trust, deal with doubts and sell the voucher (Bashir et al. 2009). In addition, the way in which vouchers are distributed and to whom may affect their effectiveness, especially when there are different preferences, for example in a household. In a randomized trial of FP vouchers in Zambia, vouchers given to women individually had a significant effect in terms of uptake, adoption of FP and unwanted births avoided, whereas vouchers given to couples had no effect on unwanted births avoided, compared to the control group (Ashraf et al. 2010). 2. Adequate supply-side capacity and quality Clearly, adequate services must be in place if DSF is to be effective in raising utilization and improving outcomes. In Nepal, for example, the roll-out of the SDIP was accompanied by considerable other investments in establishing and equipping birthing centers and improving training of staff, amongst other activities. An underutilized health system, functioning reasonably well, with competition between different suppliers, is the ideal context for introducing a DSF scheme. The introduction of DSF therefore involves an assessment of the state of the existing services, and potentially supply-side investments in raising standards prior to inflating demand. This should focus on the accessibility of services, the availability of services (staffing, opening hours etc.), having adequate infrastructure (equipment, buildings, drugs etc.), appropriate processes (infection prevention etc.) and management (staff workload, supervision etc. 3. The right economic conditions Many DSF schemes are externally funded and longer term funding will be needed to ensure their sustainability. In Nepal, for example, the SDIP was initially fully funded by DFID. Over time, the aim is to transfer the funding responsibility to the Government of Nepal, which will however be challenging. Countries which have sustained large-scale and enduring DSF policies, such as Mexico, have tended to be middle-income countries, which meet the preconditions of having reasonable state capacity to target and manage policies, the ability to finance more far-reaching transfers, a smaller proportion of their population living in poverty, and a reasonable network and standard of services (Cechini, 2009). 4. Appropriate design of package Services which are unpredictable, in terms of demand or need, are not easily accommodated in a DSF, Preventive care is favoured not only because it averts future costs for individuals and the public purse, but also because coverage goals are clear and greater consumption is generally good. For most reproductive health interventions, the identification of the target group is relatively easy, and their need for services predictable. One area for careful monitoring however is emergency obstetric care, which can be inflated or provided to the wrong group (women without clinical indications) if there is a financial incentive for providers. Another factor is the cost of the goods and services. If the cost is very low (for example, the price of purchasing condoms as a family planning method), then a relatively expensive delivery mechanism, such 14 as vouchers, is unlikely to be justified. However, offering access to longer terms, less affordable FP methods may be worthwhile. Another important decision is whether to include non-facility costs (for vouchers and cash linked to services). Where travel costs are very high (as was the case in Nepal) and where schemes target the poorest, these costs should ideally be included. 5. The right size of transfers The size of the subsidy has to be adequate to motivate behaviour change (Chapman, 2006). On the other hand, payments which are excessive are wasteful and may be benefiting those who would in any case have used services. The level of subsidy can be established iteratively through pilot projects, if these are carefully monitored. 6. Motivated and incentivized suppliers If health workers are underpaid and under-motivated, then DSF schemes will exacerbate these problems through increasing their clinical and administrative workload (and in some cases undermining the payments which they previously received from clients). In such contexts, schemes have been most effective when combined with complementary measures to address supplier incentives. In Cambodia, for example, areas with performance-based contracting and provider incentive payments performed better than those with demand side measures (vouchers and health equity funds) alone (although the incremental cost-effectiveness of each component was not assessed and would be interesting to know). However, provider incentives should be carefully designed to avoid distortions in services provided (e.g. promoting FP services which are lucrative rather than respecting client choices). 7. Strong political leadership Given the complexity and cost of many DSF schemes, ultimately there has to be considerable political commitment to sustain them. Some of the studies highlight the importance of an influential local champion (e.g. Bellows & Hamilton, 2009; Ensor, Clapham, & Prasai 2008). 8. Institutional capacity The managerial complexity of some of the schemes is evident. Systems for identifying beneficiaries, communicating schemes, channeling funds, and monitoring must be strong. If funds are not available on time, the credibility of the whole project is undermined for beneficiaries. Considerable technical support and iterative development of systems is needed. Where this develops wider systems capacity, it may have side-benefits beyond the project. However, where external agencies manage the project, the systems benefits are less clear. Handling of cash also involves financial risks which have to be managed. In Nepal and India, cash was managed by health staff and there is evidence of some degree of misuse. One rapid review of the SDIP, for example, found that 8% of incentive payments to health workers for institutional deliveries were fraudulent (CREHPA, 2008). For payments to staff conducting home deliveries (which are much harder to verify), the rate was much higher. Targeting of the poor is also a demanding activity, requiring both resources and institutional capacity, although in states where there is already an established poverty identification system (such as the BPL cards in India), then targeted schemes are more feasible and potentially efficient. 15 9. Simple payment systems Most cash-for-service and voucher schemes use fixed payments to pay providers per episode. In the case of the Uganda STI vouchers, however, payments were made per test and procedure, with the result that vetting claims was very complex and back-logs developed in settling them. 10. Good collection and use of evidence Last but not least, those policies which have been accompanied by strong information systems and regular, high-quality evaluations to inform their development are more likely to have been successful and sustained. The most notable example is PROGRESA, which has been extensively documented and subject to annual evaluations since its start. The evidence of impact has been used to sustain government investment. In the case of Nepal, findings of the implementation evaluation were fed back into improved guidelines and stronger financial systems early on in the development of the SDIP (Powell-Jackson et al. 2007). Strength and weakness of different approaches Beyond identifying general pre-conditions for success, are there lessons on the types of roles for which these different mechanisms can best be used? All financing mechanisms’ effectiveness is dependent on purpose, context, and implementation. However, some general strengths and weaknesses are drawn out in Table 5. Many of the differences noted derive from the scale of implementation: the cash for services policies which are currently well documented are all operated at national scale, for example, while voucher programs tend to be small-scale and receive more focused external technical inputs. A large-scale voucher program – Bangladesh is the key example here – may have more in common with cash for services policies in neighboring India and Nepal than with small-scale voucher programs managed in a limited area by an international NGO or contracted company. Similarly, the nature of the services themselves is important. Family planning and STI services have very clear outcome indicators and are therefore easy to monitor and evaluate. For delivery care, quality of care and health outcomes are much harder to assess. Having a facility delivery does not in itself indicate how health risks have been affected; there are no gold standards for quality of care measures; and assessing impact on mortality ratios requires large-scale, costly surveys. These will affect how schemes are implemented and how easy it is to provide robust evidence for management and evaluation purposes. These reflections indicate the extent to which the findings in this review are likely to apply to other (non-SRH) services – those with clearly defined services and easily measurable outcomes are more likely to respond well to DSF approaches. Lessons on implementation It is beyond the scope of this paper to present detailed lessons on implementation of DSF schemes. Most are complex, and at minimum, require attention to the following additional areas: Communication and marketing – Communication strategies have to reflect the nature of the products and clients. In the Uganda safe motherhood voucher scheme, for example, a combination of community-based sensitization, use of radio, and incentives for distributors was considered effective in 16 increasing uptake. In a Pakistan family planning voucher program, it was important to use trusted community members to address widely held misconceptions about the products (Boler and Harris, 2010). Quality assurance – this will involve a range of activities, including training, accreditation of providers, internal and external audits, and plan to reinforcing referral chain. Distribution strategies – particularly for vouchers, the decision about how to distribute is critical, including a choice of community-based agents and/or through retail outlets such as pharmacies. Detection and prevention of fraud – fraud can occur at many different stages and therefore requires a range of preventive strategies. For example, for a voucher scheme, fraud can take the form of the creation of fake vouchers or collusion between distributors and clients during distribution, between clients and providers during use, and/or between providers and claims processing agents during payment of vouchers. Careful systems for validating claims (including use of text messaging to contact beneficiaries directly) and zero tolerance for fraud are two important strategies to contain fraud (Boler and Harris, 2010). Conclusions and outstanding questions The paper shows the variety of DSF schemes in operation, and the variety of outcomes that they can produce, depending on their goals, design, context, funding and implementation. It is not easy to generalize about such wide-ranging policies, but it is clear that some can produce impressive results, in terms of increased utilization, if the preconditions outlined above are met. There are however a number of outstanding questions which research to date has not adequately addressed. Most importantly, the relative cost effectiveness of DSF in relation to other strategies for achieving similar goals not been assessed. That paying people to use services increases service use is not in itself surprising – of more interest is whether it does so more effectively and at lower cost than alternatives (some of these issues are explored in Table 6). This comparative cost effectiveness analysis, allowing for different contextual features, is still outstanding, in addition to the other gaps highlighted in the synthesis - for example, a need for more focus on equity analysis, and analysis of DSF schemes’ impact on financial protection, quality of care, and health outcomes. Where increased utilization is measured, there is little understanding of its determinants. Despite the rapid increase in the popularity of DSF, rigorous evaluations of DSF remain rare in low and middle income countries. Acknowledgements This article is based on a paper commissioned by the World Bank, East Asia Region. Many thanks go to Seemeen Saadat for her assistance with the literature search, and to the reviewers for their comments. 17 References Ashraf, N., Field, E. And Lee, J. (2010) Household bargaining and excess fertility: an experimental study in Zambia. http://www.econ.ubc.ca/seminars/ashraf.pdf Barber, S. and Paul J Gertler (2009) Empowering women to obtain high quality care: evidence from an evaluation of Mexico's conditional cash transfer programme Health Policy Plan vol. 24(1): p. 18-25 Barber, S. L. and Gertler, P. J. (2008) The impact of Mexico’s conditional cash transfer programme, Oportunidades, on birthweight. Tropical Medicine & International Health, vol. 13: p. 1405–1414 Bashir, Hamid, Sarfaraz Kazmi, Rena Eichler, Alix Beith, Ellie Brown (2009) Pay for Performance: Improving Maternal Health Services in Pakistan. Bethesda, Maryland: Health Systems 20/20 project, Abt Associates Inc. Bellows NM, Bellows BW, Warren C. (2010) The use of vouchers for reproductive health services in developing countries: systematic review. Trop Med Int Health. Nov 2. p. 1365-3156 Bellows, Ben, Matthew Hamilton, and Francis Kundu (2009) Vouchers for Health: Increasing Utilization of Facility-Based STI and Safe Motherhood Services in Uganda. Maternal and Child Health P4P Case Study. Bethesda, Maryland: Health Systems 20/20 project, Abt Associates Inc. Boler T and Harris, L. (2010) Reproductive Health Vouchers: from Promise to Practice. London: Marie Stopes International. Borghi, J., Anna Gorter, Peter Sandiford, and Zoyla Segura (2005) The cost-effectiveness of a competitive voucher scheme to reduce sexually transmitted infections in high-risk groups in Nicaragua Health Policy & Planning vol 20(4): pp. 222-231 Cechini, Simone (2009) Do CCT Programmes work in low-income countries? New York, NY: International Policy Centre for Inclusive Growth, United Nations Development Programme (One Pager No. 90, Poverty Practice Bureau for Development Policy). Chapman, K. (2006) Using social transfers to scale up equitable access to education and health services: background paper, DFID, London. CREHPA (2008) Rapid assessment of Safe Delivery Incentive Programme (SDIP) (Round II), Centre for Research on Environment Health and Population Activities, Kathmandu. Dagur, Vikas, Katherine Senauer, and Kimberly Switlick-Prose (2010) Paying for Performance: The Janani Suraksha Yojana Program in India. Bethesda, Maryland: Health Systems 20/20 project, Abt Associates Devadasan, N., Elias, M., John, D., Grahacharya, S., & Ralte, L. (2008) "A process evaluation of the Janani Suraksha Yojana in India," in Financing obstetric care, F. Richard, Witter S., & V. De Brouwere, eds., ITM, Antwerp 18 Ensor, T., Susan Clapham, Devi Prasad Prasai (2009) What drives health policy formulation: Insights from the Nepal maternity incentive scheme? Health Policy 90, p.247–253 Feldman BS, Zaslavsky AM, Ezzati M, Peterson KE, Mitchell M. (2009) Contraceptive use, birth spacing, and autonomy: an analysis of the Oportunidades program in rural Mexico. Stud Fam Plann. 2009 Mar; vol. 40(1): p.51-62 Gertler, P. (2000) The impact of PROGRESA on health: final report, International Food Policy Research Institute, Washington, D.C. Glassman, Amanda, Todd, Jessica Erin and Gaarder, Marie (2007) Performance-Based Incentives for Health: Conditional Cash Transfer Programs in Latin America and the Caribbean (April 23, 2007). Center for Global Development Working Paper No. 120 Gupta, I., William, J. and Rudra, S. (2010) Demand side Financing in Health: How far can it address the issue of low utilization in developing countries? Background Paper 27, World Health Report 2010; Geneva: WHO Gwatkin, D., Bhuiya, A., & Victora, C. (2004) Making health systems more equitable, The Lancet, vol. 364, pp. 1273-1280. Hanson, Kara and Powell-Jackson, Tim (2010) Financial Incentives for Maternal Health: Impact Evaluation of a National Programme in Nepal; Working Paper Series; London School of Hygiene and Tropical Medicine Hatt, Laurel, Ha Nguyen, Nancy Sloan, Sara Miner, Obiko Magvanjav, Asha Sharma, Jamil Chowdhury, Mursaleena Islam, and Hong Wang (2010) Economic Evaluation of Demand-Side Financing (DSF) for Maternal Health in Bangladesh. Bethesda, MD: Abt Associates Inc. Kelin, D., Z. Kaining and T. Songuan (2001) A draft report on MCHPAF study in China, Washington DC: World Bank Kilonzo, Margaret (2010) Pay for Performance: The Reproductive Output Based Aid Program in Kenya. Bethesda, Maryland: Health Systems 20/20 project, Abt Associates Inc. Koehlmoos, Tracey Lynn Pérez, Ali Ashraf, Humayun Kabir, Ziaul Islam, Rukhsana Gazi, Nirod Chandra Saha, Jacob Khyang (2008) Rapid Assessment of Demand-side Financing Experiences in Bangladesh; ICDDR,B working paper no. 170; September 2008: Dhaka, Bangladesh: ICDDR,B Lagarde, M., Andy Haines, Natasha Palmer (2007) Conditional Cash Transfers for Improving Uptake of Health Interventions in Low- and Middle-Income Countries: A Systematic Review; JAMA; vol. 298(16): p. 1900-1910 Lim, S., Lalit Dandona, Joseph A Hoisington, Spencer L James, Margaret C Hogan, Emmanuela Gakidou (2010) India's Janani Suraksha Yojana, a conditional cash transfer programme to increase births in health facilities: an impact evaluation, The Lancet, Volume 375, Issue 9730, 5 June 2010-11 June 2010, Pages 2009-2023 19 Meuwissen LE, Gorter AC, Segura Z, Kester AD, Knottnerus JA. (2006a) Uncovering and responding to needs for sexual and reproductive health care among poor urban female adolescents in Nicaragua. Tropical Medicine & International Health, Vol. 11(12): pp.1858-67 Meuwissen LE, Gorter AC, Kester AD, Knottnerus JA. (2006 b) Does a competitive voucher program for adolescents improve the quality of reproductive health care? A simulated patient study in Nicaragua. BMC Public Health. Vol. 7; 6: p. 204 Meuwissen, L.E., Anna C. Gorter, Andre J.A. Knottnerus (2006c) Impact of accessible sexual and reproductive health care on poor and underserved adolescents in Managua, Nicaragua: a quasi- experimental intervention study, Journal of Adolescent Health, Volume 38, Issue 1, January 2006, p. 56.e1-56.e9 Meuwissen, L. E., Gorter, A. C., Kester, A. D. M. and Knottnerus, J. A. (2006d) Can a comprehensive voucher programme prompt changes in doctors’ knowledge, attitudes and practices related to sexual and reproductive health care for adolescents? A case study from Latin America. Tropical Medicine & International Health, vol. 11: pp. 889–898 Meuwissen, L.E., Anna C. Gorter, and J. A. Knottnerus (2006e) Perceived quality of reproductive care for girls in a competitive voucher programme. A quasi-experimental intervention study, Managua, Nicaragua Int J Qual Health Care (February 2006) vol. 18(1): p. 35-42 Morris, S., Rafael Flores, Pedro Olinto, Juan Manuel Medina (2004) Monetary incentives in primary health care and effects on use and coverage of preventive health care interventions in rural Honduras: cluster randomised trial, The Lancet, Volume 364, Issue 9450, p. 2030-2037 Ngabo, F and J Humuza (201) Taking It to the Streets: Performance-Based Financing for Community Health in Rwanda; RBF brief; The World Bank; www.rbfhealth.org PAHO/WHO (2007) Social protection in health schemes for mothers, newborn & child population. Lessons learned from the Latin American regions., PAHO/WHO, Washingon D.C. Paul, V. (2010) India: conditional cash transfers for in-facility deliveries, The Lancet, Volume 375, Issue 9730, 5 June 2010-11 June 2010, Pages 1943-1944 Por, I., Horeman, D., Narin, S., & Van Damme, W. (2008) "Improving access to safe delivery for poor pregnant women: a case study of vouchers plus health equity funds in three health districts in Cambodia," in Reducing financial barriers to obstetric care, F. Richard, S. Witter, & V. De Brouwere, eds., ITG Press, Antwerp Por, I. Horemans D, Souk N, Van Damme W. (2010) Using targeted vouchers and health equity funds to improve access to skilled birth attendants for poor women: a case study in three rural health districts in Cambodia. BMC Pregnancy Childbirth. 2010 Jan 7; 10:1 Powell-Jackson, T., Neupane, B., Tiwari, S., Morrison, J., & Costello, A. (2008) Final report of the evaluation of the Safe Delivery Incentive Programme, DFID, London. 20 Powell-Jackson, T., Tiwari, S., Neupane B., Morrison, J., & Costello, A. (2007) Evaluation of the maternity incentive scheme: report of the process evaluation, SSMP Nepal, Kathmandu. Sandiford, Peter, Anna Gorter, and Micol Salvetto (2002) Vouchers for Health: Using Voucher Schemes for Output-Based Aid; Public Policy for the Private Sector Note No. 243; April 2002; Washington DC: The World Bank Schmidt, J-O, Tim Ensor, Atia Hossain, Salam Khan (2010) Vouchers as demand side financing instruments for health care: A review of the Bangladesh maternal voucher scheme; Health Policy - July 2010, Vol. 96, Issue 2, Pages 98-107 Ahmed, S. and Khan, M. (2010) A maternal health voucher scheme: what have we learned from the demand-side financing scheme in Bangladesh? Health Policy & Planning. First published online April 7, 2010 Tan, E. et al. (2005) Making services work for the poor in Indonesia. Case study 2: Vouchers for midwife services in Pemalang district, Central Java province. http://www.innovations.harvard.edu/cache/documents/6515.pdf World Bank (2010). Plan Nacer Health Insurance for the Poor in Argentina: Results-based financing secures health insurance and services for the poor. IBRD Results. Walford, V. (2008) Demand side incentives in health – learning from Asia experience. London: IHSD Briefing note 21 Table 1 Summary description of selected DSF schemes for reproductive health 22 23 24 Table 2 Impact on utilization, equity and financial protection of selected DSF schemes 25 26 27 Table 3 Impact on quality of care and health outcomes of selected DSF schemes 28 29 30 Table 4 Program costs, funding and sustainability, selected DSF schemes 31 32 33 34 Table 5 Typical strengths and risks associated with the three main DSF approaches Mechanism Summary of strengths Summary of risks or challenges Cash for Simpler version – can be implemented Higher risk of weak management and services through integrated services and at large patchy implementation, especially if no scale, if desired third party administrator More suited to categorical targeting (e.g. all Categorical targeting is always at risk of pregnant women) than individualized ‘capture’ by less poor groups Higher risk of ignoring supply-side constraints, including low quality of care Vouchers Well adapted to community targeting and Costs of identification and distribution identification of specific target groups tend to be high, especially when the target population is dispersed Marketing and distribution strategies can be used to raise awareness of neglected or Higher risk of fraud (e.g. stigmatized services (e.g. STI treatment). counterfeiting, black market Leakage also less likely for these services sales) than cash for services Few vouchers schemes are operated at Vouchers require third party administration large scale which, while costly, can be more effective at ensuring quality of services provided Allows, in principle, for easy tracking of outputs Long term Can address broader objective of providing May work better as income support than cash income support, while also promoting merit as a way of stimulating increased use of goods and services with externalities priority reproductive health services Payment mechanisms can be more direct Despite well-publicized success of and cost-effective, e.g. into client bank Opportunidades, not all schemes have 35 accounts achieved high accuracy of targeting or significant changes to behavior Tend to operate at scale and long-term, As a social protection measure, the which reduces the relative size of targeting overall cost is likely be high, making this costs most sustainable in upper middle income countries and above 36 Table 6. Some outstanding research questions on DSF 37 DSF versus user fee removal DSF schemes generally cover some part or all of service and access costs. From a consumer perspective, therefore, they can operate in a similar manner to the removal of user fees for specific services (e.g. family planning or delivery care). The main differences are that most schemes are targeted to certain income groups or areas, and some are managed by a third party structures. These third party structures may also leverage quality improvements, although again this can potentially be paralleled in an integrated structure, assuming payments to facilities are sufficient to allow some investment in quality enhancements. Whether the higher costs of establishing and managing these structures is offset by greater targeting precision or more efficient purchasing will depend in the first case largely on demand conditions and the degree of public sector management capacity. If utilization of a service is low in absolute terms across all quintiles, then the costs of targeting are unlikely to be justified. Even if wealthier women are considerably more likely to deliver in a facility than poorer ones, if the overall skilled delivery rates are low, then targeting of payments may not be appropriate. There is also an important demonstration effect to consider – when wealthier women shift to facility deliveries, this will usually be emulated over time by other socio-economic groups. On the supply side, administrative capacity is needed for good implementation of any of these policies. Effective financial management is highlighted as a challenge in most study reports, but particularly those utilizing regular government systems. DSF versus insurance The cost-effectiveness and preconditions for DSF should also be compared with insurance approaches, which can have very similar goals – increasing service uptake and reducing financial barriers – although they commonly have wider financial protection aims as well. Some countries such as Argentina have adopted an insurance approach instead of CCTs: the Plan Nacer, for example, offers coverage for a package of basic interventions to all uninsured pregnant women and children under six. Its estimated cost is $10 per capita per month (World Bank, RBF 2010). The value-added of conditionality While the Latin American CCTs such as PROGRESA have had positive impact on nutrition, health and development outcomes, the debate about the value-added of the conditionality continues, with unconditional cash transfers in other regions achieving significant gains for nutritional status of 38 children, for example (Glassman et al. 2007). Conditioning comes with a cost, both in terms of monitoring but also for households. For example, an average household at the start of Progresa faced 32 conditioned visits for health care and talks a year; these carry clear opportunity costs. Unconditional cash transfers give poor families most flexibility. Yet vouchers and conditions reassure governments and donors that money will be spent on desired goals. In practice, compliance with conditions is not always enforced rigorously (Chapman 2006). 39 The costs and benefits of poverty targeting, and alternative approaches Targeted schemes typically impose higher costs while potentially providing a more pro-poor result, but assessing both is a pragmatic issue, depending on the modalities adopted. In general, if DSF schemes do not target the poorest, they are likely to disproportionally benefit wealthier groups, whose utilization of health services is typically higher. On the other hand, individual poverty targeting often leads to under-coverage of target groups and is costly. Whether these outcomes are acceptable depends on social goals – increased utilization across all social groups may be a priority, or there may be particularly disadvantaged pockets of population which are the priority. Longer term political support for a program may also be increased if benefits are spread beyond the poorest. Decisions on whether to target individually will depend on a large number of questions, including consideration of stigmatization, the availability of data for targeting, minimizing opportunities for patronage etc. In the Uganda voucher scheme, the high cost of conducting individualized poverty assessment led to a decision to offer vouchers to all households in areas with high poverty4. By restricting the areas to sub- counties, leakage was thought to be minimized. The effectiveness of area targeting will depend on area characteristics, though, such as homogeneity of socio-economic characteristics. Densely populated and relatively homogenous areas such as urban slums may be particularly suited to geographic targeting. Paying for demand and/or paying for supply There is a shared logic to the impetus for DSF and provider pay-for-performance approaches. While demand has to be stimulated for certain services and their affordability increased, so too health workers incentives have to be ‘aligned’ and their motivation (via pay) increased. For this reason, many DSF schemes include a provider incentive component. Some design questions are also shared – what is the right level of incentive, which services should be prioritized, which group of consumers/providers to reward, and how to monitor? However, the risks are somewhat different. The main risks for DSF payments are that funds are wasted making payments to households who would have used services in any case, and that demand is generated for services which are of low quality (and consequent health benefits are not realized). High transaction costs of targeting and scheme management are also a source of inefficiency. For provider payment schemes, there are additional concerns about perverse effects, including gaming of the payments system, neglect of non-funded activities and the potential demotivation (for individuals, teams and cadres not included in the pay- for-performance systems). While both pay-for-performance and DSF have shown their potential to raise provision and consumption of services in the short-term, the longer term question is what happens when payments are withdrawn. Will changed behaviour be maintained? What are the benchmarks for assessing when 4 Defined in this instance as ‘the poorest sub-counties where poverty incidence is above 50% and poverty density is above 100 people per square km’ (Boler and Harris, 2010). 40 the right stage has been reached to make this transition? 41