37361 The Global Partnership on Output-Based Aid OBA Working Paper Series Paper No. 7, April 2006 Connecting Residential Households to Natural Gas: An Economic & Financial Analysis Franz Gerner and Scott Sinclair, World Bank Egypt is a country rich in natural gas. But by households through their savings from because of the high subsidies on LPG and the switching. relatively high connection charges for natural The system for connecting users to the gas gas, most urban and semiurban households network involves an output-based aid ap- continue to use liquefied petroleum gas (LPG) proach. The costs of connections are recovered for cooking and for heating water. That's a big through contributions by users and through a problem for the government, which provides subsidy provided by the government and substantial subsidies for LPG. This paper shows channeled through the gas distribution compa- that converting households, including low- nies. The gas distributors prefinance the costs income ones, to natural gas can be economi- of connections through debt or equity. Once cally viable: the savings from avoiding subsidies connections are verified, the distributors are on LPG can finance most of the costs of allowed to recover these costs through rates switching the residential load from LPG to over a four-year period natural gas. The remaining share can be borne About the Global Partnership on Output-Based Aid What is output-based aid? OBA is a strategy How can GPOBA help? GPOBA can assist in the for supporting the delivery of basic services-- design and development of pilot OBA projects, water, sanitation, electricity, telecommunica- and can help identify and disseminate emerging tions, transport, education, health care--where knowledge on issues related to OBA approaches policy concerns would justify public funding to through studies, publications, workshops, and complement or replace user fees. conferences. GPOBA can also contribute to the funding of subsidized payments for the provi- sion of services under OBA schemes. Global Partnership on Output Based Aid World Bank To find out more, visit Mailstop: H3-300 Washington, DC 20433, USA www.gpoba.org Supporting the delivery of basic services in developing countries Arab Republic of Egypt Connecting Residential Households to Natural Gas: An Economic & Financial Analysis FINAL REPORT April 2006 The World Bank 1 CURRENCY AND EQUIVALENT UNITS Currency Equivalent Currency Unit = Egyptian Pound (LE or EGP) Exchange Rate = Egyptian Pounds (LE) 5.8 per US$ 1.00 (as per January 1, 2006) $ = US Dollar (USD) Natural Gas Equivalent 1 kg of LPG equals 1.31 m3 of natural gas 1 mmBtu of natural gas equals 27.8 m3 of natural gas ABBREVIATIONS AND ACRONYMS bbl Barrel Bcm Billion Cubic Meters CAPEX Capital Expenditures EGAS Egyptian Natural Gas Holding Company, owned by GoE EGPC Egyptian General Petroleum Company, owned by GoE ELNG Egyptian LNG, sponsored by British Gas, Petronas, EGAS, and EGPC GASCO Egyptian Natural Gas Company, owned by GoE GoE Government of the Arab Republic of Egypt GPOBA Global Partnership on Output-Based Aid IEOC International Egyptian Oil Company, a subsidiary of Eni S.p.A IRR Internal Rate of Return JVP Joint Venture Partner LDC Local Distribution Company LE Egyptian Pound (EGP) LNG Liquefied Natural Gas LPG Liquefied Petroleum Gas, a mixture of propane and butane mmBtu Million British Thermal Units MoF Ministry of Finance MoP Ministry of Petroleum OPEX Operating Expenses Petronas Malaysian National Oil Company PSA Production Sharing Agreement SEGAS Spanish Egyptian Gas Company, sponsored by Eni, Union Fenosa, EGAS, and EGPC ton Metric Ton WTP Willingness to Pay This study was sponsored by GPOBA. GPOBA is a multi-donor trust fund that aims to fund, demonstrate and document OBA approaches in support of the sustainable delivery of basic services ­ water, sanitation, energy, electricity, telecommunication and transportation ­ to those least able to afford them and to those without access to such services. For more information on GPOBA, please visit www.gpoba.org. 2 TABLE OF CONTENTS 1. Executive Summary.................................................................................................. 5 2. Liquefied Petroleum Gas (LPG) Overview ............................................................ 9 2.1 The LPG Story in Egypt ..................................................................................... 9 2.2 Forecasting Market Prices for LPG .................................................................. 10 2.3 Economics of LPG............................................................................................ 12 3. Natural Gas Overview............................................................................................ 15 3.1 The Natural Gas Story in Egypt........................................................................ 15 3.2 Access to Natural Gas....................................................................................... 16 3.3 Natural Gas Pricing........................................................................................... 17 3.4 Connecting to Natural Gas................................................................................ 20 3.5 Economics of Natural Gas ................................................................................ 22 4. Comparison of LPG and Natural Gas Subsidies ................................................. 25 5. Economics of Connecting Households to Natural Gas........................................ 26 5.1 Willingness-to-Pay (WTP)................................................................................ 26 5.2 Household WTP................................................................................................ 26 5.3 Government WTP............................................................................................. 29 5.4 WTP of Local Distribution Companies ............................................................ 30 5.5 Savings Potential of Switching Households ..................................................... 30 5.6 Health, Environmental, Social and Safety Benefits.......................................... 32 6. Options to Increase Gas Connections ................................................................... 34 6.1 Scope of Financing Requirements .................................................................... 34 6.2 Changing Current Arrangements to Facilitate New Connections..................... 34 6.3 Financing of New Connections......................................................................... 37 TABLES Table 1: Key Economic Assumptions............................................................................................ 6 Table 2: LPG Value Chain, 2005 ................................................................................................. 10 Table 3: World Bank Oil Forecast (US$/bbl)............................................................................... 11 Table 4: Alternate Oil Forecast (US$/bbl) ................................................................................... 12 Table 5: LPG Cost to Households (LE) ....................................................................................... 12 Table 6: EGAS/EGPC Cost for Supplying LPG to Average Households (LE) ­ Base Case....... 13 Table 7: EGAS/EGPC Cost for Supplying LPG to Average Households (LE) ­ Alternate Case 14 Table 8: Retail & Commercial Price Schedule............................................................................. 18 Table 9: Commission Rate for Natural Gas Distribution (LE/m3) ............................................... 19 Table 10: Commission Payments (LE)......................................................................................... 19 Table 11: Rate Recovery by LDCs of the LDC Connection Fee ................................................. 21 Table 12: Breakdown of the Authorized Connection Fee ............................................................ 22 Table 13: EGAS/EGPC Cost for Supplying an Average Low-Volume Household (LE) ............ 23 Table 14: EGAS/EGPC Cost for Supplying an Average Middle-Volume Household (LE)........ 23 Table 15: EGAS/EGPC Cost for Supplying an Average Higher-Volume Household (LE) ........ 24 Table 16: Comparison of Subsidies for LPG and Natural Gas, 2005........................................... 25 Table 17: Estimated WTP for Connection ­ Average Low-Volume Household (LE)................. 26 Table 18: Estimated WTP for Connection ­ Average Middle-Volume Household (LE) ............ 27 Table 19: Estimated WTP for Connection ­ Average Higher-Volume Household (LE)............. 28 3 Table 20: Estimated GoE Subsidies (LE) ­ Base Case ................................................................ 29 Table 21: Estimated GoE Subsidies (LE) ­ Alternate Case ......................................................... 30 Table 22: Present Value Savings to a Household Switching to Natural Gas ............................... 31 Table 23: Economics of a Conversion (LE) ­ `Subsidized' Prices ­ Base Case.......................... 31 Table 24: Economics of a Conversion (LE) ­ `Subsidized' Prices ­ Alternate Case................... 31 Table 25: Economics of a Conversion (LE) ­ `Economic' Prices ­ Base Case........................... 32 Table 26: Economics of a Conversion (LE) ­ `Economic' Prices ­ Alternate Case.................... 32 Table 27: CAPEX Requirements for............................................................................................ 34 Table 28: Pro Forma Retail Price Schedule.................................................................................. 35 Table 29: Present Value Economics ­ Pro Forma........................................................................ 37 Table 30: Break-Even Average LPG Prices (US$/ton)................................................................ 37 Table 31: GoE WTP by Volume (LE).......................................................................................... 39 Table 32: Cost of Financing (LE)................................................................................................. 39 FIGURES Figure 1: LPG Pricing Arrangements, 2005................................................................................. 10 Figure 2: Brent Crude and Saudi Aramco Butane Price Developments, 1995-2005 ................... 11 Figure 3: Natural Gas Market Players and Industry Structure ..................................................... 16 Figure 4: Access of Households to Natural Gas in Urban Areas in Lower Egypt in 2004 .......... 17 Figure 5: Natural Gas Pricing Arrangements, 2005 ..................................................................... 20 Figure 6: Natural Gas Connection Infrastructure ......................................................................... 22 ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS This report was written by Franz Gerner and Scott Sinclair of the World Bank. The authors would like to thank Anna Bjerde, Masami Kojima, Yogita Mumssen and Umang Goswami for their valuable inputs. The report was peer-reviewed by Clive Armstrong and Radwan Shaban. 4 1. EXECUTIVE SUMMARY Egypt is a gas-rich country and in 2004 had the 15th largest proven gas reserves in the world. Domestic gas consumption was dominated by the power sector (65%), followed by the fertilizer (9%), petrochemicals (9%), other industrial sectors (9%), and the commercial and residential sectors (8%). Egypt started to export piped gas to Jordan on the Arab Gas Pipeline in 2003 and in 2005 liquefied natural gas (LNG) exports through the SEGAS LNG and ELNG terminals commenced. In 2006, Egypt became the world's sixth-largest LNG exporter with output of 17.5 billion cubic meters (Bcm) per year. The natural gas market has changed considerably in Egypt ­ the country has evolved as a major international gas exporter. Industrial customers in the domestic market are increasingly relying on natural gas to meet their energy needs. Natural gas is already used as a major source of energy and feedstock in the power, fertilizer, and petrochemicals sectors. The country now has a well-developed high-pressure transmission network in Nile Delta to supply industrial load. The Government of Egypt (GoE) aims to connect 6 million residential customers over the next 6 years in the Nile Delta and Upper Egypt at total investment costs of about LE 15 billion (US$ 2.6 billion). There are currently millions of residential customers living near existing transmission infrastructure in urban and semi-urban areas such as Cairo, Suez, and Alexandria that use relatively more expensive liquefied petroleum gas (LPG) for cooking and water heating. To connect urban residential load in Upper Egypt major new transmission pipeline development will be required. EGAS/EGPC continues to make losses for every cubic meter of gas or kilogram of LPG sold into the domestic market under current subsidized prices and this poses a major challenge to the company which faces large financing requirements to convert the residential sector to natural gas throughout Egypt. This paper aims to analyze the overall macro- and micro-economic costs and benefits of switching residential households to natural gas, to quantify the willingness to pay (WTP) of the GoE and households towards the financing of gas connections based on their potential savings, and investigate alternative financing options to increase natural gas connections. This study does not analyze whether other conversion programs (e.g., industrial or commercial load) or other fuels would have higher net benefits to the GoE. Key Economic and Financial Assumptions A key assumption is that, in the short- to medium-term, the GoE is unlikely to reach `economic' pricing for natural gas and LPG, mostly due to social considerations. With the assistance of the World Bank, the GoE has embarked on an ambitious program of economic and social transformation, including wide-ranging reforms in the areas of social safety nets and subsidies.1 In particular, the LPG subsidy is socially sensitive as it is a 1 A recently published report by the World Bank on "Egypt: Toward a More Effective Social Policy: Subsidies and Social Safety Net" from December 2005 highlights that energy subsidies are substantial with economic costs of 8.1 percent of GDP in 2004. 5 `fuel of the poor' and any phasing out should only be done after an expanded social safety net has been put in place. Also, some price increases are planned at the residential level; the timing and scope of those adjustments remain uncertain. For the purpose of this paper, it was assumed that LPG and natural gas prices will continue to be subsidized in the short- to medium-term, which will require the contribution of the GoE towards the financing of gas connections from its savings on avoided LPG subsidies. However, the analysis also demonstrates that if `economic' prices are charged for LPG and natural gas, middle- and higher volume households would be willing to pay for all gas connection costs due to the relatively high prices of LPG. In this context, the authors have not analyzed in detail the LPG consumption levels of various household income groups (poor, low-income, middle-income, and high-income households); the low-, middle-, and higher-volumes used for the analysis are indicative only. In addition, this paper focuses on the direct `savings' benefits to the GoE and households when converting to natural gas. Due to the lack of available data, this paper does not aim to quantify indirect benefits to households, including health, environmental, social benefits, which if calculated would further strengthen the overall economics of converting households and increase their willingness to pay for connection. Hence, the economic and financial analysis and the associated findings in this report may be overly conservative. The key economic assumptions made in this paper are set out below. Table 1: Key Economic Assumptions Natural Gas Average price paid by EGAS/EGPC to upstream producers US$ 2.50/mmBtu Average economic retail price US$ 3.50/mmBtu Average total costs of connecting a household LE 2500 (US$ 431) Household connection fee payment LE 1500 (US$ 259) Government contribution to total connection fee LE 1000 (US$ 172) LPG Regulated price per 12.5-kg cylinder at official LPG distribution outlets LE 2.5 (US$ 0.43) Average purchase price per 12.5-kg cylinder from private distributors LE 7.0 (US$ 1.21) Average monthly LPG consumption Low-volume household 1 cylinder (12.5 kg) Middle-volume household 2 cylinders (25 kg) Higher-volume household 3.3 cylinders (42 kg) LPG Price Economic price of LPG Import Parity Price Economic price indexing See Table 3 Discount Rate Annual rate based on Egyptian LE sovereign rates 10% Indirect Benefits of Switching to Natural Gas Social, health, environmental and safety benefits Not quantified 6 Major Findings on Conversion Economics for Residential Households The economic and financial analysis in this paper demonstrates that despite (a) the absence of a heating load in Egypt and (b) the high investment costs for gas distribution development, it is economically viable to finance network development and connect households that currently use 1.25 or more 12.5-kg LPG cylinders (equivalent to 20m3 of natural gas) monthly. This volume break-even point and the analytical findings are based on an average 2005 LPG market price, delivered to Egypt, of US$ 440/ton (plus a 15- percent margin to reflect the costs of transporting, filling, and distributing the cylinders within Egypt). This delivered economic price for LPG is indexed over a 20-year period using the World Bank Oil Forecast, February 1, 2006 (see Table 3). The authors also calculated the LPG break-even prices for low-, middle-, and higher- volume households. At an average LPG price above US$ 399/ton over a 20-year investment period, it would be economically viable to connect low-volume households. For medium- and higher-volume households, an average LPG price above US$ 241/ton and US$ 165/ton, respectively, would justify conversion. At current `subsidized' LPG and natural gas prices, the combined savings of switching to natural gas (the aggregate savings of GoE and a middle- or higher-volume household, as the case may be) exceed the total investment requirement for a new gas connection. However, middle-volume households do not convert to natural gas because their share of the potential savings is less than their required contribution of LE 1500 (US$ 259) to the connection fee. At `economic' prices for gas and LPG, middle- and higher-volume households would have an economic incentive to finance the total gas connection fee of LE 2500 (US$ 431) by themselves. At economic prices, the GoE does not have any net savings from households switching and hence would be unwilling to contribute towards gas connection financing. There are two impediments to connecting lower-volume households to the natural gas network, at both `economic' and `subsidized' prices, (assuming that those households are low income and poor households). The first is the inability of lower-volume households to bear the LE 1500 (US$ 259) costs of connection, even when payments are spread over time. Although a household makes an annual saving by converting from LPG to natural gas, it is not enough to fund a new connection. The second impediment relates to the timing of the GoE's LPG subsidy savings and the government's connection payments, which causes a negative cash-flow problem for the EGAS/EGPC. The economic and financial analysis in this paper is based solely on direct `savings' benefits to households and the GoE. The environmental, social, health, and safety benefits of households converting to natural gas have not been quantified. Indeed, there are indications from other jurisdictions around the world that customers are willing to pay a significant `convenience premium' for having access to natural gas. A typical 7 distribution network development also comprises commercial customers (e.g., restaurants, shops, etc.) who tend to be imbedded in residential areas. Mixing of household groups, incorporating indirect benefits to households and including commercial load into the analysis may substantially improve the economics of connections and it is likely that this will make it economic viable to connect all households, including low volume households, to natural gas. In conclusion, this paper argues that the sooner residential households are switched from using LPG to natural gas the higher the net benefits for Egypt and provides analytical support to the GoE to embark on its ambitious gas conversion program. It is important to note, however, that changes in the international LPG market price forecast would alter the economics of conversion. The analysis further highlights that while households have net benefits to switching to natural gas and should be contributing towards the financing of new gas connections, the GoE has the largest net benefits due to the savings on LPG subsidies. 8 2. LIQUEFIED PETROLEUM GAS (LPG) OVERVIEW 2.1 THE LPG STORY IN EGYPT To meet their domestic energy needs for cooking and water heating, most residential customers in Egypt who are not connected to the natural gas network use LPG. There is no heating load in Egypt. The poor use LPG for cooking. Higher-income groups also use LPG for water heating, and gas consumption per household increases significantly once those heaters are installed. Higher-income households also tend to use more energy per capita for cooking than lower-income households. The market for LPG in Egypt is large. In 2004, Egypt consumed about 3.1 million tons of LPG at a market value of about LE 9.1 billion (US$ 1.6 billion), all of which is handled by EGAS/EGPC. EGAS/EGPC bought about 2 million tons of LPG from its joint venture partners (JVPs) in Egypt and the remaining 1.1 million tons were bought in international markets. EGAS/EGPC pays JVPs market prices for LPG. In 2005, the international market price, delivered to Egypt, for Mediterranean LPG, averaged approximately US$ 440/ton (LE 2551/ton) at an annual average crude oil price of about US$ 53/bbl. Adding a 15-percent margin to reflect the costs of transporting, filling, and distributing the LPG cylinders within Egypt gave an estimated delivered economic cost of LE 2934/ton (US$ 506/ton). However, in Egypt, the domestic LPG price is fixed at LE 200/ton (US$ 35/ton), which accounted for only 7 percent of its economic costs in 2005. Consequently, the total economic subsidy the GoE paid for LPG in the domestic market was around LE 8.5 billion (US$ 1.5 billion) or 1.5 percent of GDP. A combination of increasing international energy prices, a depreciating Egyptian Pound (LE) against the US Dollar,2 and high subsidies on the domestic LPG price has created major negative budgetary implications for the GoE.3 Table 2 provides indicators of the impact of LPG subsidies on the macroeconomic position of Egypt in 2005. The GoE regulates and administers the price per 12.5-kg cylinder at LE 2.5 (US$ 0.43) at official LPG distribution outlets. However, those outlets are limited and often not located in or near residential areas. A network of unregulated private distributors has emerged who sell LPG cylinders to end-users for about LE 7 (US$ 1.21) each. Hence, for every cylinder sold, the private LPG distributors have revenues of about LE 4.5 (US$ 0.78); their distribution costs offsetting these revenues are not known. The LPG value chain is shown in Table 2. 2The Egyptian Pound has depreciated by almost 50 percent over the last five years against the US Dollar. 3 Irrespective of whether the LPG is bought from JVPs or in international markets, the appropriate benchmark price for calculating the economic subsidy for LPG is the import parity price. 9 Table 2: LPG Value Chain, 2005 Aggregate Wholesale 12.5-kg Heating Market* Market Cylinder Value (LE billions) (LE/ton) (LE/cylinder) (LE/mmBtu) International market price (US$ 440/ton) 7.911 2552 31.9 54.0 Plus 15% transportation/filling/distribution +1.187 +383 +4.8 +8.1 Economic cost, delivered 9.098 2935 36.7 62.1 GoE Subsidy -8.478 -2735 -34.2 -57.8 Selling price at official EGAS distribution outlet 0.620 200 2.5 4.2 Plus private distributors' mark-up +1.116 +360 +4.5 +7.6 Selling price by private distributors 1.736 560 7.0 11.8 Source: World Bank calculations; *based on 3.1 million tons of LPG consumption. In 2005, after the mark-up by the private LPG distribution network, residential customers, regardless of volume, paid about 19 percent of the economic value of LPG. Figure 1 illustrates the financial flows among the GoE, EGAS/EGPC, the LPG market, the private distribution market, and residential customers and sets out the current LPG pricing arrangements. As can be seen, the GoE subsidy is LE 57.8/mmBtu, as compared with LE 14.3 - 18.5/mmBtu for natural gas (see Table 16). It is understood that the subsidy is currently borne by EGAS/EGPC and that there is no financial transfer between GoE and the company. Figure 1: LPG Pricing Arrangements, 2005 Government of Egypt Residential Customer Subsidy LE 57.8/mmBtu International LPG Markets Upstream Payments EGAS/ LPG Payments Private LPG Payments Residential LE 54.0/mmBtu EGPC LE 4.2/mmBtu Distributors LE 11.8/mmBtu Customers Joint Venture Partners Source: World Bank. 2.2 FORECASTING MARKET PRICES FOR LPG A strong relationship exists between crude oil and butane prices. (LPG is a mixture of butane and propane. Butane and propane are closely correlated and similarly priced.) 10 Figure 2 demonstrates this relationship. For the period 1995 to 2005, the correlation coefficient for Brent Crude and Saudi Aramco Butane was 0.87.4 Figure 2: Brent Crude and Saudi Aramco Butane Price Developments, 1995-2005 70 500 65 450 60 55 Butane 400 lbb 50 350 45 $/SUt 40 300 35 250 on)t/$SU( 30 enrB 200 25 nea 20 150 utB 15 100 10 Brent 5 50 0 Jan-95 Au Ma Oc Ma De Ju Fe Se No Jun-01 Jan-02 Au Ma Oc Ma De Ju 0 g-95 r-9 6 t-96 y-9 7 c-97 l-98 b-99 p-99 Apr-0 0 v-00 g-02 r-0 3 t-03 y-0 4 c-04 l-05 Source: World Bank calculations based on Platts data. Based on this correlation of oil and butane prices, this paper, for analytic purposes, will use the World Bank Oil Forecast, February 1, 2006, shown in Table 3, to index LPG prices in the future. Table 3: World Bank Oil Forecast (US$/bbl) Base Case Crude Oil, Average, Real (1990 dollars) 2005 49.89 2006 53.83 2007 49.80 2008 46.76 2009 43.81 2010 40.93 2015 29.58 Source: World Bank, February 1, 2006. For the purposes of sensitivity analysis, this paper will also compare results indexed with the oil forecast in Table 4, which is from the Annual Energy Outlook 2006, published by the Energy Information Administration of the US Government. 4The correlation coefficient is a numerical value which identifies the strength of relationship between two variables. Maximum Value=1.0; Minimum Value=-1.0. A correlation of +1.0 means that two variables are perfectly correlated. 11 Table 4: Alternate Oil Forecast (US$/bbl) Alternate Case Crude Oil, Average, Real (2004 dollars) 2005 49.70 2006 53.95 2007 51.46 2008 48.98 2009 46.49 2010 43.99 2015 43.00 Source: Energy Information Administration, Annual Energy Outlook 2006. 2.3 ECONOMICS OF LPG Table 5 shows the subsidized and economic costs of the LPG purchased by low-volume, middle-volume, and higher-volume households, using the World Bank Oil Forecast for forecasting economic costs. Low-volume households consume an estimated 12.5 kg (1.0 cylinder) of LPG per month or 150 kg per year (7.10 mmBtu/yr); middle-volume households consume 25 kg (2.0 cylinders) of LPG per month or 300 kg per year (14.19 mmBtu/yr); and higher-volume households consume an estimated 41.7 kg (3.3 cylinders) of LPG per month or 500 kg per year (23.65 mmBtu/yr). Table 2 shows that, over the long-term, households are projected to pay about 27 percent of the `economic' cost of LPG if they continued to be subsidized at current levels. Table 5: LPG Cost to Households (LE) Year Low-Volume (150 kg/yr) Middle-Volume (300 kg/yr) Higher-Volume (500 kg/yr) Subsidized Economic Subsidized Economic Subsidized Economic 1 84 475 168 950 280 1583 2 84 439 168 879 280 1465 3 84 413 168 825 280 1375 4 84 387 168 773 280 1289 5 84 361 168 722 280 1204 6 84 336 168 672 280 1120 7 84 311 168 623 280 1038 8 84 294 168 589 280 981 9 84 278 168 555 280 925 10 84 261 168 522 280 870 11 84 261 168 522 280 870 12 84 261 168 522 280 870 13 84 261 168 522 280 870 14 84 261 168 522 280 870 15 84 261 168 522 280 870 16 84 261 168 522 280 870 17 84 261 168 522 280 870 18 84 261 168 522 280 870 19 84 261 168 522 280 870 20 84 261 168 522 280 870 Total 1680 6165 3360 12330 5600 20551 Present Value (10% discount rate) 715 2917 1430 5833 2384 9722 Source: World Bank calculations, using World Bank Oil Forecast, February 1, 2006. 12 Table 6 shows the cost to the GoE of subsidizing LPG sales to low-volume, middle- volume, and higher-volume households. The inflows represent the receipts of EGAS/EGPC at the official LPG distribution centers (at LE 2.5/cylinder). The outflows represent the price at which EGAS/EGPC purchases LPG in the international markets plus 15 percent for transportation and handling. Table 6: EGAS/EGPC Cost for Supplying LPG to Average Households (LE) ­ Base Case Low-Volume (150 kg/yr) Middle-Volume (300 kg/yr) Higher-Volume (500 kg/yr) Year Cost to Cost to Cost to Inflows Outflows EGAS/ Inflows Outflows EGAS/ Inflows Outflows EGAS/ EGPC EGPC EGPC 1 30 -475 -445 60 -950 -890 100 -1583 -1483 2 30 -439 -409 60 -879 -819 100 -1465 -1365 3 30 -413 -383 60 -825 -765 100 -1375 -1275 4 30 -387 -357 60 -773 -713 100 -1289 -1189 5 30 -361 -331 60 -722 -662 100 -1204 -1104 6 30 -336 -306 60 -672 -612 100 -1120 -1020 7 30 -311 -281 60 -623 -563 100 -1038 -938 8 30 -294 -264 60 -589 -529 100 -981 -881 9 30 -278 -248 60 -555 -495 100 -925 -825 10 30 -261 -231 60 -522 -462 100 -870 -770 11 30 -261 -231 60 -522 -462 100 -870 -770 12 30 -261 -231 60 -522 -462 100 -870 -770 13 30 -261 -231 60 -522 -462 100 -870 -770 14 30 -261 -231 60 -522 -462 100 -870 -770 15 30 -261 -231 60 -522 -462 100 -870 -770 16 30 -261 -231 60 -522 -462 100 -870 -770 17 30 -261 -231 60 -522 -462 100 -870 -770 18 30 -261 -231 60 -522 -462 100 -870 -770 19 30 -261 -231 60 -522 -462 100 -870 -770 20 30 -261 -231 60 -522 -462 100 -870 -770 Total -5565 -11130 -18551 Present Value (10% discount rate) -2661 -5323 -8871 Source: World Bank calculations, using World Bank Oil Forecast, February 1, 2006. Table 7 shows the same information as Table 6 but using the Alternate Oil Forecast. 13 Table 7: EGAS/EGPC Cost for Supplying LPG to Average Households (LE) ­ Alternate Case Low-Volume (150 kg/yr) Middle-Volume (300 kg/yr) Higher-Volume (500 kg/yr) Year Cost to Cost to Cost to Inflows Outflows EGAS/ Inflows Outflows EGAS/ Inflows Outflows EGAS/ EGPC EGPC EGPC 1 30 -478 -448 60 -956 -896 100 -1593 -1493 2 30 -456 -426 60 -912 -852 100 -1519 -1419 3 30 -434 -404 60 -868 -808 100 -1446 -1346 4 30 -412 -382 60 -824 -764 100 -1373 -1273 5 30 -390 -360 60 -779 -719 100 -1299 -1199 6 30 -388 -358 60 -776 -716 100 -1293 -1193 7 30 -386 -356 60 -772 -712 100 -1287 -1187 8 30 -384 -354 60 -769 -709 100 -1281 -1181 9 30 -383 -353 60 -765 -705 100 -1275 -1175 10 30 -381 -351 60 -762 -702 100 -1270 -1170 11 30 -384 -354 60 -769 -709 100 -1281 -1181 12 30 -388 -358 60 -776 -716 100 -1293 -1193 13 30 -391 -361 60 -783 -723 100 -1305 -1205 14 30 -395 -365 60 -790 -730 100 -1317 -1217 15 30 -399 -369 60 -797 -737 100 -1328 -1228 16 30 -404 -374 60 -808 -748 100 -1346 -1246 17 30 -409 -379 60 -818 -758 100 -1364 -1264 18 30 -415 -385 60 -829 -769 100 -1382 -1282 19 30 -420 -390 60 -840 -780 100 -1399 -1299 20 30 -425 -395 60 -850 -790 100 -1417 -1317 Total -7520 -15040 -25066 Present Value (10% discount rate) -3257 -6513 -10855 Source: World Bank calculations, using Alternate Oil Forecast. For every cylinder of LPG sold into the domestic residential sector, EGAS/EGPC suffers a substantial loss. 14 3. NATURAL GAS OVERVIEW 3.1 THE NATURAL GAS STORY IN EGYPT By the end of 2004, Egypt had, with 1870 Bcm, the 15th largest proven gas reserves in the world. In 2005, the Ministry of Petroleum (MoP), based on studies conducted by international companies, estimated an additional 3400 Bcm as probable and possible reserves. Most of this increase has come about as a result of new natural gas discoveries offshore in the Mediterranean and some finds in the Western Desert.5 Privately and publicly owned companies operate in all segments of Egypt's natural gas chain. Upstream, international oil & gas majors including IEOC (a subsidiary of Eni S.p.A.), Shell Egypt NV, BG Egypt S.A., and BP Egypt Gas Co., operate on- and offshore natural gas fields in the Western Desert and in the Nile Delta and Mediterranean. There are also smaller international oil companies operating in natural gas exploration and production activities in Egypt, including Apache Egypt Companies. Egypt has two operational LNG terminals, ELNG, located at Idku, and SEGAS LNG, located at Damietta. Egypt expects to be the world's sixth largest LNG exporter by 2006, with output of 17.5 Bcm/year (7.5 Bcm/year from SEGAS and 10 Bcm/year from ELNG). Egypt started to export piped natural gas to Jordan from the Arab Gas Pipeline in mid- 2003. The first leg of the Arab Gas Pipeline, 265 km from El-Arish in Sinai (Egypt) to Aqaba (Jordan), supplies 1.1 Bcm/year of natural gas to Aqaba Power Station. (The pipeline has a total annual capacity of 10 Bcm.) A 395 km extension of the pipeline across Jordan has been completed and it is anticipated that Jordan will consume 3.4 Bcm/year of Egyptian natural gas in the near future. In addition, Egypt plans to add natural gas exports to Syria and Lebanon (and potentially to Turkey and to Europe) when the pipeline is extended beyond Jordan and has already signed some initial agreements. The downstream sector is dominated by the Egyptian Natural Gas Holding Company (EGAS) and Egyptian General Petroleum Corporation (EGPC), both state-owned companies, which are the only suppliers of natural gas into the domestic market (and the only importer of LPG); Egyptian Natural Gas Company (GASCO), the state-owned gas transmission company; and nine Local Distribution Companies (LDCs).6 All natural gas networks in Egypt are owned by EGAS/EGPC. Nine LDCs operate the system on behalf of EGAS/EGPC to supply gas to approximately 2 million commercial and residential customers. The GoE allocated the distribution concessions to private and publicly owned companies based on criteria such as number of residential households connected per annum, 5BP Statistical Review of World Energy June 2005 and Egypt Country Analysis Brief, Energy Information Administration, US Department of Energy, May 2005. 6In Egypt, pipeline pressure is measured in bar. One bar can be approximated to one atmosphere (more precisely, 1 bar equals 0.9869 atmospheres). The transmission network operates at 70 bar and above, and the distribution network at 7 bar and below. 15 technical qualification, reasonable rate of return, and others. Of the nine LDCs, one is fully state-owned (Egyptian Town Gas), one is majority state-owned (Egypt Gas), and seven are majority privately owned (Fayum Gas Company, Nile Valley Gas Company, National Gas Company (NatGas), Transgas Company, Repco Gas, National Gas S.A.E., and City Gas). Some LDCs, including NatGas, Nile Valley Gas Company, Fayum Gas, and City Gas, also operate transmission networks. Figure 3 illustrates the industry structure of the Egyptian natural gas sector. Figure 3: Natural Gas Market Players and Industry Structure Export Domestic Market Non-Associated Gas LNG Power Sector ·SEGAS ·ELNG Residential Upstream Customers Network & Transmission Distribution/ Processing Supply Commercial Arab Gas Pipeline Customers ·Jordan Industrial Associated Gas Customers Joint Venture Partners GASCO 9 LDCs ·International majors Some LDCs ·2 majority state-owned ·EGPC/EGAS ·7 privately owned Source: World Bank. 3.2 ACCESS TO NATURAL GAS The Nile Delta has an extensive coverage of high pressure transmission network to supply commercial and industrial customers, mostly power generators and urban areas including Cairo, Suez, and Alexandria. There are some distribution networks in urban and semi-urban areas in the Delta but the vast majority of residential households continue to use LPG to meet their domestic energy needs. Upper Egypt is currently not connected to natural gas network. Figure 4 shows that 44 percent of the richest household groups living in urban areas in Lower Egypt have access to natural gas, while only one tenth of the urban poor and 9 percent of low-income households are connected to natural gas distribution network. 16 Figure 4: Access of Households to Natural Gas in Urban Areas in Lower Egypt in 2004 50 44 45 40 e) 35 agt 30 cen erP( 25 20 20 ccessA15 13 10 9 10 5 0 Poor 2nd quintile 3rd quintile 4th quintile Rich Urban Population Quintiles Source: Egypt-Toward a More Effective Social Policy: Subsidies and Social Safety Net, World Bank, draft, September 2005. There are millions of residential households that live near existing transmission gas infrastructure in urban and semi-urban areas in Lower Egypt that are not connected and continue to use more heavily subsidized and expensive LPG. 3.3 NATURAL GAS PRICING The buying and selling of natural gas in the domestic market is dominated by EGAS/EGPC, GASCO, and the LDCs. In the Egyptian context, the term `tariff' refers to the payment by EGAS/EGPC to transmission and distribution companies for the operation of the gas connection network owned by EGAS/EGPC. `Price' reflects the total payment by customers for natural gas delivered to their premises. Gas retail prices are regulated by the Ministry of Petroleum (MoP) in consultation with the Cabinet of Ministers. EGAS/EGPC sources the natural gas to supply the domestic market from either the `equity gas' it receives under its Production Sharing Agreements (PSAs), for which no cash payment is required, or `joint venture gas' it purchases from its JVPs.7 EGAS/EGPC pays for joint venture gas at prices that are linked to international crude oil prices.8 There is a contractual `ceiling' price for the joint venture gas EGAS/EGPC buys from the JVPs, ranging from US$ 2.50-2.65/mmBtu. There are also a few `older' PSAs 7However, EGAS/EGPC is paying tax & royalty on the equity and joint venture gas to the GoE. 8 Despite `equity gas' being `free' for EGAS/EGPC, in economic terms the value for that gas is its opportunity costs (eg export value). 17 in place where no price ceiling is incorporated in the contract.9 In 2005, equity and joint venture gas each accounted for about 50 percent of domestic natural gas consumption. Under the current pricing scheme, customers pay less than the full economic price for natural gas. EGAS/EGPC sells natural gas to power plants and industrial customers at a fixed price of US$ 1.00/mmBtu. Residential and commercial customers pay a volume- based block price that is collected by the LDCs and passed through to EGAS/EGPC. The current annualized retail and commercial price schedule is set out in Table 8. Table 8: Retail & Commercial Price Schedule Annual Consumption Retail & Commercial Price LE/m3 LE/mmBtu US$/mmBtu 0-360 m3/yr 0.10 2.78 0.48 360-720 m3/yr 0.20 5.56 0.96 above 720 m3/yr 0.30 8.34 1.44 Source: EGAS. A residential customer is defined as a customer who uses up to 720 m3/yr of natural gas. Commercial customers use above 720 m3/yr. Residential and commercial customers are both served from the distribution network. For bulk transmission services, EGAS/EGPC pays GASCO (and some LDCs) a volume- based fee of LE 0.007/m3. This is equivalent to a postage-stamp transmission rate of LE 0.19/mmBtu (US$ 0.03/mmBtu). Each LDC has entered into one or more contracts with EGAS/EGPC pursuant to which the LDC seeks to convert LPG users to natural gas. Current and potential arrangements for financing the costs of connection are described in section 3.4 below and subsequent chapters of this paper. For distribution services, each LDC receives from EGAS/EGPC a Commission. Under the new arrangements, the Commission is based on quantities of natural gas sold, as set forth in Table 9 below. 9For the purposes of this paper, natural gas is assumed to be purchased by EGAS/EGPC at an average price of US$ 2.50/mmBtu. This price is based on information provided by the MoP and based on average contract prices in existing PSAs. 18 Table 9: Commission Rate for Natural Gas Distribution (LE/m3) Year Fee Rate OPEX rate Commission Rate 1 0.10 0.15 0.25 2 0.10 0.15 0.25 3 0.10 0.15 0.25 4 0.10 0.15 0.25 5 0.10 0.18 0.28 6 0.10 0.20 0.30 7 0.10 0.23 0.33 8 0.10 0.27 0.37 9 0.10 0.30 0.40 10 0.10 0.34 0.44 11 0.10 0.39 0.49 12 0.10 0.41 0.51 13 0.10 0.44 0.55 14 0.10 0.46 0.56 15 0.10 0.49 0.59 16 0.10 0.52 0.62 17 0.10 0.55 0.65 18 0.10 0.59 0.69 19 0.10 0.62 0.72 20 0.10 0.66 0.76 Source: NatGas, September 2005. The Commission payable to an LDC is subject to a cap, however. The cap is a ceiling on the aggregate Commission payable to the LDC, calculated based on a maximum Commission per customer (LE 100 for the first ten years and LE 125 for the following ten years). Table 10 below shows marginal Commissions by LDCs for adding low- volume, middle-volume, and higher-volume households at a natural gas consumption rate equivalent to LPG consumption. Table 10: Commission Payments (LE) Year Low-Volume Middle-Volume Higher-Volume (197 m3/yr) (394 m3/yr) (657 m3/yr) 1 49.3 98.6 100.0 2 49.3 98.6 100.0 3 49.3 98.6 100.0 4 49.3 98.6 100.0 5 55.2 100.0 100.0 6 59.2 100.0 100.0 7 65.1 100.0 100.0 8 73.0 100.0 100.0 9 78.9 100.0 100.0 10 86.8 100.0 100.0 11 96.6 125.0 125.0 12 100.6 125.0 125.0 13 108.5 125.0 125.0 14 110.5 125.0 125.0 15 116.4 125.0 125.0 16 122.3 125.0 125.0 17 125.0 125.0 125.0 18 125.0 125.0 125.0 19 125.0 125.0 125.0 20 125.0 125.0 125.0 Source: World Bank calculations. 19 This paper has not explored the cost structures of the LDCs. For service providers like the LDCs, it is likely that the costs of servicing customers are largely fixed costs and do not vary much, if any, with the consumption level of the customer. The MoP has set these Commission rates and caps (and the GASCO fees as well) in its capacity as sector regulator. This paper assumes that the Commission payment scheme is reviewed periodically by the GoE and adjusted as necessary to allow operators to recover its prudently incurred operating costs. Figure 5 illustrates the financial flows among the GoE, EGAS/EGPC, the upstream producers, GASCO, the LDCs, and customers and sets out the current natural gas pricing arrangements. As can be seen, the GoE subsidy is LE 14.3 - 18.5/mmBtu, as compared with LE 57.8/mmBtu for LPG (see Table 16). Figure 5: Natural Gas Pricing Arrangements, 2005 Government of Egypt Residential Customer Subsidy LE 14.3 - 18.5/mmBtu Network Service Fee GASCO LE 0.19/mmBtu Equity Gas Commission LE 4.2 - 6.9/mmBtu Gas Payments Residential LE 2.8 ­ 5.6/mmBtu Customers LDCs Upstream Payments LE 14.5/mmBtu EGAS/ Gas Payments Commercial EGPC LE 8.4/mmBtu Customers Joint Venture Gas Contract Industrial Gas LE 5.8/mmBtu Customers Gas Contract Power LE 5.8/mmBtu Stations S ource: World Bank. 3.4 CONNECTING TO NATURAL GAS The MoP, in consultation with the Cabinet of Ministers, is the price regulator for the natural gas sector in Egypt. All transmission and distribution network development must be approved by EGAS/EGPC. GASCO and the LDCs prepare annual network expansion plans, and pre-finance transmission and distribution network development which they eventually recover through connection fee payments from households and EGAS/EGPC. On July 1, 2005, the MoP set the Connection Fee for a new connection to the network at LE 2500 (US$ 431) nationwide. The Connection Fee is split into two parts: (a) an authorized Household Connection Fee of LE 1500 (US$ 259) that is paid by the 20 household and (b) an authorized LDC Connection Fee of LE 1000 (US$ 172) that is paid by EGAS/EGPC. All households contribute the Household Connection Fee, up-front prior to connection, except that, in some cases, the National Bank of Egypt offers customer financing of Household Connection Fees. This financing is for up to seven years. In these cases, the relevant LDC facilitates the financing through coordinated billing and collection. LDCs pre-finance the LDC Connection Fee through debt or equity, as each LDC chooses. LDCs are allowed to recover the LDC Connection Fee from EGAS/EGPC through rates over four years, without interest,10 upon verification of connections. (See Table 11.) The LDC Connection Fee is `output-based aid' (`OBA') in the terminology of the World Bank and the Global Partnership on Output-Based Aid (GPOBA). In simplified terms, there are two key elements to an OBA approach: (a) performance-based, and (b) explicit subsidies. The performance-based element means that service providers are for the most part paid after the delivery of an agreed output ­ in this case household connections to the natural gas network. Therefore, the service provider takes on pre-financing risk, and is only compensated after it has proven service delivery. The explicit subsidy element means that an identified group of consumers (in this case, everybody being connecting to the gas network) is not paying the full cost of receiving the service. The two elements come together under OBA, whereby some of the cost of providing the service to the user is covered by a donor or the government, but the related payment is paid to the service provider only after it delivers the service. Table 11: Rate Recovery by LDCs of the LDC Connection Fee Year LDC Connection Fee (LE) 1 400 2 200 3 200 4 200 Total 1000 Present Value (10% discount rate) 816 Source: MoP. On behalf of EGAS, the owner of all natural gas distribution networks in Egypt, the LDCs procure the new connections for which they have been authorized by EGAS/EGPC, most likely using the contracting services of one of three active contractors: HouseGas (an affiliate of City Gas and Repco Gas), Egypt Gas (owned by the GoE), or Orascom Construction Industries Company (not known to be an affiliate of any LDC). Table 12 shows estimated component costs of a new connection. 10Under the previous scheme, which is still applicable to pre-existing gas connections, LDCs are allowed to recover capital expenditures over five years, with an authorized rate of return of 18 percent. 21 Table 12: Breakdown of the Authorized Connection Fee LE · Networks (material, regulators, excavation, laying, 760 backfilling, permits, reinstatement) · External Installations (material, scaffolding, finishing 750 ­sleeves for holes, repainting, etc.) · Internal Installations (material, meter kits, finishing) 760 · Conversion of Appliances (material, appliances 230 conversion, flues & vents installations) Total Connection Fee 2500 Source: Information provided by NatGas, September 2005. The Connection Fee includes the costs of constructing the distribution pipeline, connecting the household to the distribution main, and installing all necessary internal and external equipment, including the meter and the conversion of existing appliances. Figure 6 below illustrates the infrastructure that is covered by the natural gas Connection Fee. Figure 6: Natural Gas Connection Infrastructure Source: World Bank. In addition, for each new connection, EGAS/EGPC pays the relevant LDC a one-time Administrative Fee of LE 30 (US$ 5) to defray the costs of setting up the new account. 3.5 ECONOMICS OF NATURAL GAS Under the current pricing scheme, customers pay natural gas commodity prices subsidized by the GoE while delivery costs (i.e., Commission and GASCO charges) are absorbed by EGAS/EGPC. This results in costs to the GoE as shown in the following tables. The inflows represent the receipts of EGAS/EGPC through the gas commodity price charges to residential customers. The outflows represent the price EGAS/EGPC pays for the gas to upstream producers and the commission and GASCO tariff and LDC connection and administrative fees. 22 Table 13: EGAS/EGPC Cost for Supplying an Average Low-Volume Household (LE) INFLOWS OUTFLOWS LDC Year Commodity Upstream Connection Fee Cost to (197 m3/yr @ Producers Commission + + EGAS/EGPC $ 0.48/mmBtu) ($ 2.50/mmBtu) GASCO Administrative Fee 1 20 -103 -51 -430 -564 2 20 -103 -51 -200 -334 3 20 -103 -51 -200 -334 4 20 -103 -51 -200 -334 5 20 -103 -57 - -140 6 20 -103 -61 - -144 7 20 -103 -66 - -150 8 20 -103 -74 - -158 9 20 -103 -80 - -163 10 20 -103 -88 - -171 11 20 -103 -98 - -181 12 20 -103 -102 - -185 13 20 -103 -110 - -193 14 20 -103 -112 - -195 15 20 -103 -118 - -201 16 20 -103 -124 - -207 17 20 -103 -126 - -210 18 20 -103 -126 - -210 19 20 -103 -126 - -210 20 20 -103 -126 - -210 Total 394 -2058 -1798 -1030 -4491 Present Value (10% discount 168 -876 -637 -843 -2188 rate) Source: World Bank calculations. Table 14: EGAS/EGPC Cost for Supplying an Average Middle-Volume Household (LE) INFLOWS OUTFLOWS LDC Year Commodity Upstream Connection Fee Cost to (394 m3/yr @ Producers Commission + + EGAS/EGPC $ 0.52/ mmBtu) ($ 2.50/mmBtu) GASCO Administrative Fee 1 43 -206 -101 -430 -694 2 43 -206 -101 -200 -464 3 43 -206 -101 -200 -464 4 43 -206 -101 -200 -464 5 43 -206 -103 - -266 6 43 -206 -103 - -266 7 43 -206 -103 - -266 8 43 -206 -103 - -266 9 43 -206 -103 - -266 10 43 -206 -103 - -266 11 43 -206 -128 - -291 12 43 -206 -128 - -291 13 43 -206 -128 - -291 14 43 -206 -128 - -291 15 43 -206 -128 - -291 16 43 -206 -128 - -291 17 43 -206 -128 - -291 23 INFLOWS OUTFLOWS LDC Year Commodity Upstream Connection Fee Cost to (394 m3/yr @ Producers Commission + + EGAS/EGPC $ 0.52/ mmBtu) ($ 2.50/mmBtu) GASCO Administrative Fee 18 43 -206 -128 - -291 19 43 -206 -128 - -291 20 43 -206 -128 - -291 Total 858 -4115 -2300 -1030 -6587 Present Value (10% discount 365 -1752 -930 -843 -3159 rate) Source: World Bank calculations. Table 15: EGAS/EGPC Cost for Supplying an Average Higher-Volume Household (LE) INFLOWS OUTFLOWS LDC Year Commodity Upstream Connection Fee Cost to (657 m3/yr @ Producers Commission + + EGAS/EGPC $ 0.70/ mmBtu) ($ 2.50/mmBtu) GASCO Administrative Fee 1 95 -343 -105 -430 -782 2 95 -343 -105 -200 -552 3 95 -343 -105 -200 -552 4 95 -343 -105 -200 -552 5 95 -343 -105 - -352 6 95 -343 -105 - -352 7 95 -343 -105 - -352 8 95 -343 -105 - -352 9 95 -343 -105 - -352 10 95 -343 -105 - -352 11 95 -343 -130 - -377 12 95 -343 -130 - -377 13 95 -343 -130 - -377 14 95 -343 -130 - -377 15 95 -343 -130 - -377 16 95 -343 -130 - -377 17 95 -343 -130 - -377 18 95 -343 -130 - -377 19 95 -343 -130 - -377 20 95 -343 -130 - -377 Total 1910 -6859 -2342 -1030 -8321 Present Value (10% discount 813 -2920 -950 -843 -3899 rate) Source: World Bank calculations. For every cubic meter of natural gas sold into the domestic residential sector, EGAS/EGPC suffers a loss. This reduces EGAS/EGPC's financial capability to approve and finance new distribution network development. 24 4. COMPARISON OF LPG AND NATURAL GAS SUBSIDIES Natural gas sales prices in Egypt are subsidized by the GoE, but, on an mmBtu- equivalent basis, the subsidies for natural gas are modest in comparison with those for LPG. Table 16 illustrates the 2005 subsidy rates in Egypt for natural gas for recently connected consumers (the costs of a natural gas connection are not included), and compares these with LPG pricing. As explained above, the LDC handling fees and the retail commodity charges vary for different consumption levels. The table shows the subsidy levels for the average low-volume, middle-volume, and higher-volume household. Table 16: Comparison of Subsidies for LPG and Natural Gas, 2005 Natural Gas Value Chain (LE/mmBtu) LPG Value Chain (LE/mmBtu) Middle- Higher- Low-Volume Volume Volume (7.1 mmBtu/yr) (14.2 mmBtu/yr) (23.7 mmBtu/yr) Cost of LPG at port of entry Cost of natural gas into Egypt (US$440/ton) 54.0 14.5 14.5 14.5 at wellhead (US$ 2.50/mmBtu) Value of LPG at EGAS Value of natural gas official distribution center with GASCO (includes 15% 62.1 14.7 14.7 14.7 transportation costs transportation costs) (LE 0.007/m3) Value of natural gas 21.3 21.3 18.3 with LDC distribution costs (i.e., Commission) GoE Subsidy -57.8 -18.5 -18.2 -14.3 GoE Subsidy Selling price of LPG to private distributors 4.2 (LE 2.5/cylinder) Cost to household Cost to household of LPG of natural gas (block (includes transport costs pricing based on from distribution center) 11.8 2.8 3.0 4.0 average (LE 7.0/cylinder) consumption as outlined in Table 8) Source: World Bank calculations. As Table 16 illustrates, households using natural gas today pay about 24-34 percent of the cost of the equivalent heat content of subsidized LPG. If natural gas transportation costs (i.e., Commission and GASCO fees) were also borne by households, then households using natural gas would pay about 66-83 percent of the cost of the equivalent heat content of subsidized LPG. 25 5. ECONOMICS OF CONNECTING HOUSEHOLDS TO NATURAL GAS 5.1 WILLINGNESS-TO-PAY (WTP) The GoE proposes to connect an additional 6 million households to the natural gas network over the six years. This section analyzes the saving potentials of the households (low-volume, middle- volume, and higher-volume), the GoE, and LDCs by switching to natural gas and the `willingness' of each to contribute to the capital costs of new natural gas connections under current `subsidized' and `economic' prices for natural gas and LPG. Willingness to pay (WTP) can be defined as the maximum amount (or breakeven amount) households, the GoE, and LDCs are prepared to pay for connecting households, although in practice any new allocation of connection costs will be more acceptable if benefits and/or burdens are shared. As mentioned above, the official Connection Fee is currently LE 2500 (US$ 431) plus a one-time Administrative Fee of LE 30 (US$ 5). 5.2 HOUSEHOLD WTP One conservative method for estimating the WTP of households for converting to natural gas is to compare post-conversion energy costs to costs being paid for alternative energy sources (e.g., LPG) to meet domestic energy needs. In Egypt, natural gas transportation costs (i.e., Commission and GASCO) are being absorbed by EGAS/EGPC, so, for comparability, the WTP can be calculated as the difference between the subsidized and/or economic costs currently paid for delivered LPG and the subsidized and/or economic costs paid for delivered natural gas. Households should be willing to pay the same as before conversion, and, considering the other benefits of natural gas (e.g., convenience), may be willing to pay even more. This analysis does not quantify such indirect benefits. Table 17 shows the annual savings for an average low-volume household that converts to natural gas use, based on consumption of 7.10 mmBtu/yr and current subsidized LPG and gas prices. Table 17: Estimated WTP for Connection ­ Average Low-Volume Household (LE) LPG Natural Gas Annual Savings to Household (150 kg/yr) (197 m3/yr) (WTP) after Conversion Year Commodity Commodity Commission + EGAS pays Household pays (LE 7/cylinder) ($ 0.48/mmBtu) GASCO Commission + Commission + GASCO GASCO 1 84 20 51 64 14 2 84 20 51 64 14 3 84 20 51 64 14 4 84 20 51 64 14 5 84 20 57 64 8 6 84 20 61 64 4 7 84 20 66 64 -2 8 84 20 74 64 -10 26 LPG Natural Gas Annual Savings to Household (150 kg/yr) (197 m3/yr) (WTP) after Conversion Year Commodity Commodity Commission + EGAS pays Household pays (LE 7/cylinder) ($ 0.48/mmBtu) GASCO Commission + Commission + GASCO GASCO 9 84 20 80 64 -16 10 84 20 88 64 -24 11 84 20 98 64 -34 12 84 20 102 64 -38 13 84 20 110 64 -46 14 84 20 112 64 -48 15 84 20 118 64 -53 16 84 20 124 64 -59 17 84 20 126 64 -62 18 84 20 126 64 -62 19 84 20 126 64 -62 20 84 20 126 64 -62 Total WTP 1286 -512 Present Value WTP (10% discount rate) 547 -90 Internal Rate of Return on Household Connection Fee (LE 1530 investment) NA NA Source: World Bank estimates. The table above indicates that under current subsidized natural gas prices, a low-volume household that converts to natural gas should be able to pay about LE 547 towards the cost of connection or the service fees for natural gas (i.e., Commission and GASCO), with a modest increase in out-of-pocket costs after six years in the latter case. Table 18 shows the annual savings for an average middle-volume household that converts to natural gas use, based on consumption of 14.19 mmBtu/yr. Table 18: Estimated WTP for Connection ­ Average Middle-Volume Household (LE) LPG Natural Gas Annual Savings to Household (300 kg/yr) (394 m3/yr) (WTP) after Conversion Year Commodity Commodity Commission + EGAS pays Household pays (LE 7/cylinder) ($ 0.52/mmBtu) GASCO Commission + Commission + GASCO GASCO 1 168 43 101 125 24 2 168 43 101 125 24 3 168 43 101 125 24 4 168 43 101 125 24 5 168 43 103 125 22 6 168 43 103 125 22 7 168 43 103 125 22 8 168 43 103 125 22 9 168 43 103 125 22 10 168 43 103 125 22 11 168 43 128 125 -3 12 168 43 128 125 -3 13 168 43 128 125 -3 14 168 43 128 125 -3 15 168 43 128 125 -3 16 168 43 128 125 -3 17 168 43 128 125 -3 18 168 43 128 125 -3 19 168 43 128 125 -3 27 LPG Natural Gas Annual Savings to Household (300 kg/yr) (394 m3/yr) (WTP) after Conversion Year Commodity Commodity Commission + EGAS pays Household pays (LE 7/cylinder) ($ 0.52/mmBtu) GASCO Commission + Commission + GASCO GASCO 20 168 43 128 125 -3 Total WTP 2502 202 Present Value WTP (10% discount rate) 1065 135 Internal Rate of Return on Household Connection Fee (LE 1530 investment) 5.5% NA Source: World Bank estimates. The above table illustrates that under current subsidized natural gas prices, a middle- volume household that converts to natural gas should be able to pay about LE 1065 towards the cost of connection or the service fees for natural gas (i.e., Commission and GASCO), with a very small increase in out-of-pocket costs after ten years in the latter case. Even if the middle-volume household pays the service fees for natural gas (i.e., Commission and GASCO), it should be willing to make a small contribution to the connection costs (by this analysis, LE 135). Table 19 shows the annual savings for an average higher-volume household that converts to natural gas use, based on consumption of 23.65 mmBtu/yr. Table 19: Estimated WTP for Connection ­ Average Higher-Volume Household (LE) LPG Natural Gas Annual Savings to Household (500 kg/yr) (657 m3/yr) (WTP) after Conversion Year Commodity Commodity Commission + EGAS pays Household pays (LE 7/cylinder) ($ 0.70/mmBtu) GASCO Commission + Commission + GASCO GASCO 1 280 95 105 185 80 2 280 95 105 185 80 3 280 95 105 185 80 4 280 95 105 185 80 5 280 95 105 185 80 6 280 95 105 185 80 7 280 95 105 185 80 8 280 95 105 185 80 9 280 95 105 185 80 10 280 95 105 185 80 11 280 95 130 185 55 12 280 95 130 185 55 13 280 95 130 185 55 14 280 95 130 185 55 15 280 95 130 185 55 16 280 95 130 185 55 17 280 95 130 185 55 18 280 95 130 185 55 19 280 95 130 185 55 20 280 95 130 185 55 Total WTP 3690 1348 Present Value WTP (10% discount rate) 1571 621 Internal Rate of Return on Household Connection Fee (LE 1530 investment) 10.7% NA Source: World Bank estimates. 28 The table above indicates that under the current subsidized natural gas prices, a higher- volume household that converts to natural gas should be able to pay about LE 1571 towards the cost of connection or the service fees for natural gas (i.e., Commission and GASCO). Even if the higher-volume household pays the service fees for natural gas (i.e., Commission and GASCO), it should be willing to make a 41 percent contribution to the Household Connection Fee (by this analysis, LE 621). All household groups have an economic incentive to provide some contribution towards financing of gas connections. However, except in the case of a higher-volume household that does not have to pay the Commission and GASCO tariffs, households are unwilling to pay the total Household Connection Fee of LE 1500 based on their potential savings from switching. 5.3 GOVERNMENT WTP The WTP of the GoE to pay for natural gas connections to households is presumed to be the net savings that the GoE will realize from avoided subsidies on LPG consumption less subsidies on natural gas. The current rates of subsidy are shown in Table 16. Table 20 shows the annual subsidies (WTP) of the GoE, using the World Bank Oil Forecast to index LPG prices. The LPG subsidies are taken from Table 6 and the natural gas subsidies are taken from Tables 13, 14, and 15. Table 20: Estimated GoE Subsidies (LE) ­ Base Case Low-Volume Middle-Volume Higher-Volume EGAS pays Household EGAS pays Household EGAS pays Household Commission pays Commission pays Commission pays + GASCO Commission Commission Commission + GASCO + GASCO + GASCO + GASCO + GASCO Present Value LPG 2661 5323 8871 Less Present Value natural gas 2188 1551 3159 2230 3899 2950 Present Value GoE WTP 473 1110 2163 3093 4972 5921 Internal Rate of Return (LE 1530 investment) NA 6.5% 17.0% 24.9% 46.9% 54.4% Source: World Bank calculations, using World Bank Oil Forecast, February 1, 2006. Table 21 shows the same information but using the Alternate Oil Forecast for indexing future LPG prices. 29 Table 21: Estimated GoE Subsidies (LE) ­ Alternate Case Low-Volume Middle-Volume Higher-Volume EGAS pays Household EGAS pays Household EGAS pays Household Commission pays Commission pays Commission pays + GASCO Commission Commission Commission + GASCO + GASCO + GASCO + GASCO + GASCO Present Value LPG 3257 6513 10855 Less Present Value natural gas 2188 1551 3159 2230 3899 2950 Present Value GoE WTP 1068 1706 3354 4283 6956 7905 Internal Rate of Return (LE 1530 investment) 6.4% 11.5% 23.7% 30.0% 52.2% 59.0% Source: World Bank calculations, using Alternate Oil Forecast. The tables above shows the significant incentives for the GoE to contribute substantially to the costs of Household Conversion Fees. The WTP calculations demonstrate that it is economically viable to finance gas connections to middle- and higher-volume households and to contribute to the connection financing to low-volume households. 5.4 WTP OF LOCAL DISTRIBUTION COMPANIES As mentioned above, each LDC receives from EGAS/EGPC LE 1000 for each new gas connection and LE 1500 from the household. The LDC pre-finances its LDC Connection Fee of LE 1000. Under the current arrangements, the first EGAS/EGPC installment of 40 percent is recovered through rates after three months of natural gas supply to the connected household, and the balance is recovered through rates in installments of 20 percent a year for three years, without interest, as shown in Table 11. This arrangement for pre-financing the LDC Connection Fee has a present value savings to the GoE of LE 184 (US$ 32), using a 10% discount rate. LDCs should be allowed to recover reasonable CAPEX and OPEX costs for supplying households and make a reasonable rate of return on their investments. As these costs are periodically reviewed by the MoP in their capacity as sector regulators, this paper will assume these costs are currently reasonable and through periodic adjustments will remain so. Therefore, the LDCs are assumed to have no further WTP for Household Connection Fees. 5.5 SAVINGS POTENTIAL OF SWITCHING HOUSEHOLDS The above analysis demonstrates the macro- and micro-economic benefits of switching households from LPG to natural gas under current LPG and natural gas prices. Table 22 recaps the present value savings to households (from section 5.2 above). 30 Table 22: Present Value Savings to a Household Switching to Natural Gas Low-Volume Middle-Volume Higher-Volume (7.10 mmBtu/yr) (14.19 mmBtu/yr) (23.65 mmBtu/yr) EGAS pays Household EGAS pays Household EGAS pays Household Commission pays Commission pays Commission pays + GASCO Commission Commission Commission + + GASCO + GASCO + GASCO + GASCO GASCO LPG consumption quantity (kg/yr) 150 kg/yr 300 kg/yr 500 kg/yr present value (10% discount rate) (LE) 715 715 1430 1430 2384 2384 Equivalent natural gas consumption quantity (m3/yr) 197 m3/yr 394 m3/yr 657 m3/yr present value (10% discount rate) (LE) 168 805 365 1295 813 1763 Present Value WTP (10% discount rate) (LE) 547 -90 1065 135 1571 621 Source: World Bank calculations. The analysis shows the savings/loss of each household group when switching to natural gas from LPG. As described in section 3.3 above, current subsidized retail natural gas prices for residential customers vary depending on the volume consumed. Table 20 estimates the GoE net subsidy savings from switching a marginal customer in each household group to natural gas. Table 23 aggregates the WTP from the previous sections. Table 23: Economics of a Conversion (LE) ­ `Subsidized' Prices ­ Base Case Low-Volume Middle-Volume Higher-Volume EGAS pays Household EGAS pays Household EGAS pays Household Commission pays Commission pays Commission pays + GASCO Commission Commission Commission + GASCO + GASCO + GASCO + GASCO + GASCO Present Value household WTP 547 -90 1065 135 1571 621 Present Value GoE WTP 473 1110 2163 3093 4972 5921 Present Value LDC WTP NA NA NA Present Value total WTP 1020 1020 3228 3228 6543 6543 Internal Rate of Return (LE 1530 investment) 5.0% 5.0% 26.4% 26.4% 60.0% 60.0% Source: World Bank calculations, using World Bank Oil Forecast, February 1, 2006, 10% discount rate. Table 24 shows the same information using the Alternate Oil Forecast. Table 24: Economics of a Conversion (LE) ­ `Subsidized' Prices ­ Alternate Case Low-Volume Middle-Volume Higher-Volume EGAS pays Household EGAS pays Household EGAS pays Household Commission pays Commission pays Commission pays + GASCO Commission Commission Commission + GASCO + GASCO + GASCO + GASCO + GASCO Present Value household WTP 547 -90 1065 135 1571 621 Present Value GoE WTP 1068 1706 3354 4283 6956 7905 Present Value LDC WTP NA NA NA Present Value total WTP 1615 1615 4419 4419 8527 8527 Internal Rate of Return (LE 1530 investment) 10.9% 10.9% 31.3% 31.3% 64.2% 64.2% Source: World Bank calculations, using Alternate Oil Forecast, 10% discount rate. 31 As shown in Table 23, at subsidized prices for LPG and natural gas, the combined present value WTP of the GoE and households of switching to natural gas is calculated at LE 1020 (US$ 176) for the low-volume households, LE 3228 (US$ 557) for middle- volume households, and LE 6543 (US$ 1128) for higher-volume households. Table 25 shows the present value WTP of households at `economic' prices for LPG and natural gas. Middle- and higher-volume households have financial incentives to pay the total connection fee of LE 2500 and will switch to natural gas. Low-volume households would only be willing to pay up to LE 1500 towards financing of gas connections. At `economic' prices the GoE is unwilling to contribute towards gas connection financing due to the lack of subsidy savings. Table 25: Economics of a Conversion (LE) ­ `Economic' Prices ­ Base Case Economic Low-Volume Middle-Volume Higher-Volume Present Value household WTP 1691 3381 5635 Present Value GoE WTP NA NA NA Present Value LDC WTP NA NA NA Present Value total WTP 1691 3381 5635 Internal Rate of Return (LE 2530 investment) 3.4% 16.5% 33.5% Source: World Bank calculations, using World Bank Oil Forecast, February 1, 2006, 10% discount rate. Table 26 shows the same information using the Alternate Oil Forecast. Table 26: Economics of a Conversion (LE) ­ `Economic' Prices ­ Alternate Case Economic Low-Volume Middle-Volume Higher-Volume Present Value household WTP 2286 4571 7619 Present Value GoE WTP NA NA NA Present Value LDC WTP NA NA NA Present Value total WTP 2286 4571 7619 Internal Rate of Return (LE 2530 investment) 8.5% 21.6% 38.4% Source: World Bank calculations, using Alternate Oil Forecast, 10% discount rate. This analysis demonstrates that it is economic to convert from LPG to natural gas for middle- and higher-volume households both under current `subsidized' and `economic' prices for LPG and natural gas. Although the low-volume households are not attractive by themselves to convert, by targeting areas with a combination of income groups and possibly commercial customers, it should be possible to convert all income groups economically. 5.6 HEALTH, ENVIRONMENTAL, SOCIAL AND SAFETY BENEFITS In addition to the economic savings from switching to natural gas, there are social, health, environmental and safety benefits to the households. Currently, poor households collect LPG cylinders from distribution outlets, an activity that is time-consuming, requires substantial efforts, and has gender implications. 32 Poor households often do not have transportation facilities and have to carry the relatively heavy LPG cylinder between the household and the cylinder shop. This task is performed mostly by women. A 12.5-kg LPG cylinder has a total weight of about 18 kg (12.5 kg is the weight of the LPG and the 5.5 kg is the weight of the metal cylinder). The weight of the cylinders often causes rough handling and can result in explosion and injury to persons (e.g., burns). Switching households from LPG to natural gas also has additional health and environmental benefits as it significantly reduces CO2 emissions. (1 ton of natural gas causes 2.6 tons of CO2 emissions compared with 1 ton of LPG that causes 2.95 tons of CO2 emissions.) There is also the `convenience' factor of natural gas. Experiences from other jurisdictions show that households are willing to pay a premium for access to natural gas. Anecdotal evidence in Egypt shows that households are willing to pay finance charges for conversion to natural gas that are multiples higher than the cost of LPG would otherwise have been under today's subsidized prices. This analysis does not quantify any of those indirect benefits to households. To quantify those benefits a comprehensive socio-economic survey would have to be carried out and hence this analysis and the associated WTP calculations may be overly conservative. 33 6. OPTIONS TO INCREASE GAS CONNECTIONS The previous chapters establish the economic basis for converting domestic LPG users to natural gas under the existing regime. This chapter sets out the scope of financing requirements for gas connections and sets out various options for improving the economics and for financing the cost of new natural gas connections. 6.1 SCOPE OF FINANCING REQUIREMENTS The GoE plans to build 6 million natural gas connections over the next six years at a total investment cost of LE 15 billion (US$ 2.6 billion). Under the current arrangements, LE 6 billion (US$ 1.1 billion) will have to be raised by LDCs and LE 9 billion (US$ 1.6 million) by consumers. On an annual basis, the total investment is LE 2.5 billion (US$ 430 million) per year on average. Of this, under the current arrangements, LDCs will have to raise LE 1 billion (US$ 170 million) and consumers will have to raise LE 1.5 million (US$ 260 million) annually. Table 27 sets out the CAPEX requirements for natural gas connections in the next fifteen years. Table 27: CAPEX Requirements for Natural Gas Connections until 2012 LE (billion) 6-Year Investment Requirement 15.0 · Total LDC Connection Fees 6.0 · Total Household Connection Fees 9.0 Annual Investment Requirement 2.5 · Total LDC Connection Fees 1.0 · Total Household Connection Fees 1.5 Source: World Bank calculations. 6.2 CHANGING CURRENT ARRANGEMENTS TO FACILITATE NEW CONNECTIONS This section will investigate options for improving the economics of natural gas connection and delivery by altering the existing pricing and other arrangements, to facilitate new connections. · Should natural gas prices increase to include Commission and GASCO charges? To maximize economic efficiencies and create the appropriate price signals, customers should pay the total costs of being supplied with energy, including the gas commodity price and transportation and service fees. 34 In Egypt, the natural gas commodity charges are substantially below equivalent LPG charges, both of which are subsidized by the GoE. Rather than create a windfall for customers converting to natural gas (ignoring connection costs), it would appear reasonable for natural gas prices to include the costs of delivery. The analysis in section 5.2 above shows that including the Commission and GASCO charges in the current price of natural gas results in savings for consumers for the first six years for low-volume households, and for the first ten years for middle-volume households, and in all years for higher-volume households. The analysis suggests that charging natural gas customers for the Commission and GASCO amounts is feasible. The financing analysis in section 6.3 below assumes this change. These amounts may be fashioned as service fees or increases in commodity charges. · Can the natural gas price be increased even more? The analysis in section 5.2 above shows a small reduction in fuel costs for low-volume and middle-volume households in the early years after conversion. Higher-volume households show savings of about 25 percent (present value) after connection. Changes in gas prices for high-volume consumers, the upper steps of retail block pricing (see Table 8), may be warranted. Consideration could be given to the following: Table 28: Pro Forma Retail Price Schedule Current Arrangement Pro Forma* Retail Price Annual Consumption Retail Price (LE/m3) Annual Consumption (LE/m3) 0-360 m3 0.10 0-360 m3 0.10 360-720 m3 0.20 360-500 m3 0.30 above 720 m3 0.30 above 500 m3 0.50 * N.B. For illustrative purposes only. Although a conclusion cannot be reached without further study, such a lowering of the consumption thresholds in the retail pricing scheme would appear to have no effect on low-volume or middle-volume households, and would reduce the subsidy for higher- volume households by about LE 400 (present value). Raising the retail prices as indicated in Table 28 (at the current thresholds) would appear to have no effect on low- volume households, but would reduce the subsidy for middle-volume and higher-volume households by about LE 30 and LE 250 (present value), respectively. It would appear that combining the reduction in thresholds with the pricing increases for those upper levels has a compounding effect only on the higher-volume households, reducing their subsidy by LE 925. Given the need for further study, the financing analysis in section 6.3 below assumes no change in the current pricing arrangements. 35 · Can there be a decrease in Commission and/or GASCO rates? Or a decrease in the `ceiling' commission? The LDCs and GASCO should be entitled to reimbursement of reasonable costs of operating the gas networks. As sector regulator, the GoE should periodically review the Commission and GASCO rates. An analysis of adjusting these rates is beyond the scope of this paper. However, for illustrative purposes, one could assume further efficiency gains of LDCs in the operation of distribution network and a decrease in the `ceiling' commission to, say, LE 90 for the first ten years and LE 112.5 for the second ten years, a 10 percent reduction from today's rates. If implemented, this change would slightly increase the attractiveness of natural gas to all households from about LE 10 to LE 90 present value. The financing analysis in section 6.3 below assumes no change in Commission and/or GASCO rates. · Can the Connection Fee be reduced? In recent years, the GoE has adjusted the Connection Fee periodically. Under the current arrangement, LDCs are providing an economic subsidy of LE 184 (see section 5.4 above) to the connection cost of LE 2500 (7.4 percent). As sector regulator, the GoE should periodically review the Connection Fee for reasonableness. An analysis of adjusting this fee is beyond the scope of this paper. However, for illustrative purposes, one could assume the Household Connection Fee is reduced to LE 1300. Obviously, the present value effect of such a reduction is an improvement of LE 200. The financing analysis in section 6.3 below assumes no change in the Connection Fee. · Can upstream payments be reduced? The upstream producers are receiving on average about US$ 2.50/mmBtu for natural gas. Given today's oil prices, and the existence of two LNG facilities and a pipeline for export, the analysis in the next bullet and section 6.3 below assumes no scope for reduction of the payments to upstream producers. · Pro Forma Analysis For illustrative purposes only, the following Table 29 shows the effect on the economics of new gas connections of implementing the possible changes described above (i.e., increasing gas prices, decreasing the Commission cap, and reducing the Connection Fee). In comparing with Table 23, one can see that although the subsidy for the higher-volume bracket would be decreased (primarily due to the adjustments in the block-pricing) as a result of the pro forma changes, the overall economics are little affected. 36 Table 29: Present Value Economics ­ Pro Forma Low-Volume Middle-Volume Higher-Volume Household Household Household pays pays pays Commission Pro Forma Commission Pro Forma Commission Pro Forma + GASCO + GASCO + GASCO (Table 23) (Table 23) (Table 23) Present Value household WTP -90 -78 135 193 621 -211 Present Value GoE WTP 1110 1110 3093 3122 5921 6845 Present Value LDC WTP NA NA NA Present Value total WTP 1020 1032 3228 3315 6543 6634 Internal Rate of Return (LE 1530/1330 investment) 5.0% 6.9% 26.4% 31.5% 60.0% 70.4% · What is the break-even average LPG price below which the avoided LPG subsidies no longer pay for the connection fees? An alternate approach to this economic analysis is to calculate the levelized LPG price below which the net savings generated by avoided LPG subsidies no longer pay for the costs of new connection. As previously mentioned, the above analysis uses the World Bank Oil Forecast, February 1, 2006, to index international LPG market prices. This forecast starts with the recent international LPG market price of US$ 440/ton for 2005, steps up in 2006, and declines in `real' terms thereafter (see Table 3). Table 30 below calculates instead the fixed `real' international LPG market price below which investing in a new connection is uneconomic. The table shows the break-even prices using the savings available to GoE plus the savings of a household after conversion to natural gas. Table 30: Break-Even Average LPG Prices (US$/ton) Low-Volume Middle-Volume Higher-Volume Break-Even using Total WTP 399 241 165 Source: World Bank calculations. This analysis shows that so long as the GoE forecast of `real' international LPG market prices averages above US$ 399/ton, it will be economic for the GoE to finance the conversion of consumers as low as one cylinder of LPG per month. 6.3 FINANCING OF NEW CONNECTIONS In looking at financing options, this paper will assume Commission and GASCO charges are included in natural gas prices, but other options discussed in the previous section are not immediately implemented given the difficult policy implications and their limited impacts. · Should the LDC Connection Fee be increased? Under the current scheme, LDCs are pre-financing the LDC Connection Fee of LE 1000, and recovering it from EGAS/EGPC over four years, without interest. There is no known problem with this part of the current scheme. In fact, the terms are attractive to the GoE and should not be reduced unless part of a regulatory adjustment of rates. 37 Of course, if LDCs are willing to pre-finance more than LE 1000, with below-market return on investment, this would improve the economics of conversion. However, this paper will assume the MoP and MoF, as regulators of the sector, have set the LDC Connection Fee and terms at a reasonable level. · Should households finance the Household Connection Fee? Financing of the Household Connection Fee of LE 1500 presents significant challenges. As shown in Table 23, even with EGAS/EGPC absorbing the Commission and GASCO payments, all but the higher-volume households should be expected to decline the offer to convert under the current pricing arrangements.11 With households paying the Commission and GASCO charges, as this section 6.3 assumes, no households should be inclined to pay the Household Connection Fee. If households were offered financing of LE 1500 from the National Bank of Egypt, for seven years and at an interest rate of 12 percent (including insurance), as some are, the household would incur costs of about LE 330 per year. This alone is more that the LPG costs of a higher-volume household. As shown in Tables 17, 18, and 19, the capacity for households to pay for the Household Connection Fee is very limited, from nil to LE 185 per year in the best case (higher- volume household with EGAS/EGPC subsidy of Commission and GASCO). One would assume that households should bear a part of the cost of connection for policy reasons, and the GoE should consider the appropriate level of household contribution to a new connection. For purposes of this analysis, it is assumed that the Household Connection Fee is paid by others, as discussed below. As noted above, this paper's approach to Household WTP is conservative and considers only the relative costs of service. Consideration should be given to conducting some field research to determine the approximate value to consumers of the `convenience' of using natural gas. A high `convenience' factor could significantly increase Household WTP and thereby decrease the need for the GoE to pay for connections. · Should LDCs pre-finance the Household Connection Fee? Utility companies customarily pre-finance assets for recovery over time through rates. In simplistic terms, the investment is levelized over the recovery period using an authorized return on ratebase (i.e., an interest rate). The rate of return would represent the weighted cost of capital of the utility, and the recovery period would typically be related to the life of the asset. Reviewing these calculations is a common function of regulators. In Egypt, the financial capacity for LDC pre-financing of new connections is limited to the amount that can be recovered from the GoE through rates (i.e., the GoE WTP as 11The economic analysis used a discount rate of 10%. Households would likely have a higher discount rate, which would serve to make payment of the Household Connection Fee even less attractive. 38 shown in Table 31). Presumably, the GoE would be willing to increase fees paid to LDCs by an amount equal to its net reduction in subsidies. With front-end loading of the LDC Connection Fee under current arrangements, the GoE WTP is uneven in the early years, and some financial engineering may be necessary for LDC pre-financing of new connections to be attractive to financial intermediaries. Table 31: GoE WTP by Volume (LE) Low-Volume Middle-Volume Higher-Volume Natural Natural Natural Year LPG GoE LPG GoE LPG GoE Subsidy Gas Gas Gas WTP Subsidy WTP Subsidy WTP (Table 6) Subsidy (Table 6) Subsidy (Table 6) Subsidy (Table 13*) (Table 14*) (Table 15*) 1 445 513 -68 890 593 297 1483 677 806 2 409 283 126 819 363 456 1365 447 917 3 383 283 99 765 363 402 1275 447 828 4 357 283 73 713 363 350 1189 447 741 5 331 83 248 662 163 499 1104 247 856 6 306 83 223 612 163 449 1020 247 773 7 281 83 198 563 163 400 938 247 690 8 264 83 181 529 163 366 881 247 634 9 248 83 164 495 163 332 825 247 578 10 231 83 148 462 163 299 770 247 523 11 231 83 148 462 163 299 770 247 523 12 231 83 148 462 163 299 770 247 523 13 231 83 148 462 163 299 770 247 523 14 231 83 148 462 163 299 770 247 523 15 231 83 148 462 163 299 770 247 523 16 231 83 148 462 163 299 770 247 523 17 231 83 148 462 163 299 770 247 523 18 231 83 148 462 163 299 770 247 523 19 231 83 148 462 163 299 770 247 523 20 231 83 148 462 163 299 770 247 523 Source: World Bank calculations; *as mentioned in section 6.2, Tables 13, 14, and 15 have been adjusted so households pay Commission + GASCO. The following table shows the cost of financing the Household Connection Fee (LE 1500, annual principal and interest payments, levelized) over a range of terms and interest rates. Table 32: Cost of Financing (LE) Term (years) Interest Rate 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 10% 473 344 281 244 220 204 192 183 176 12% 494 365 302 265 242 226 215 207 201 14% 515 386 323 288 265 250 239 232 226 16% 536 407 345 310 289 274 265 258 253 18% 558 429 368 334 313 300 291 284 280 20% 579 451 391 358 338 325 317 312 308 Source: World Bank calculations. Without any special credit enhancement, LDCs may be presumed to borrow in the range of 6-8 years and 14-16 percent interest, although specialized lenders like the International Finance Corporation (IFC) may be able to lend to the LDCs for longer tenors. At these terms, LDC pre-financing of the Household Connection Fee would be attractive to the 39 GoE, based on the GoE WTP, only for higher-volume consumers. Better financing terms might be available with a regulatory order approving the inclusion of the financing cost in rates, although probably not fully reflecting EGAS/EGPC credit due to regulatory risks. If EGAS/EGPC were to guarantee payment of the investment recovery amounts in a legally assignable form, lenders should be able to finance at EGAS/EGPC terms, which might be 10-12 years and 12-14 percent interest. The GoE may wish to investigate supplemental external credit enhancement from institutions like the World Bank. A partial credit guarantee from the World Bank would create a blended credit, partly GoE and partly World Bank. Such an arrangement might induce lenders to reach up to 18 years at 12 percent interest and fees, although this would need to be tested in the banking community. If these types of terms are available, with cross-subsidization between income groups, a program might be designed to cover the broader market for conversion to natural gas, even more so if households contribute a nominal co-payment. Financial tailoring, particularly during the lumpy early years, could make a significant improvement, if lenders have that flexibility. · Should EGAS/EGPC finance the Household Connection Fee? As mentioned above, EGAS/EGPC is the owner of all natural gas transmission and distribution assets in Egypt, and will be the owner of the new connections being installed. One option is for EGAS/EGPC to finance the Household Connection Fee (LE 1500 less any nominal co-payment by households) directly. Again, the GoE's appetite for financing of connections is the GoE WTP as shown in Table 31. As mentioned above, the unevenness of the GoE WTP in the early years may require some year-to-year tailoring of financing for a closer match of the GoE's savings and financing. Within the Egyptian financial markets, EGAS/EGPC should be well positioned to borrow at rates more attractive than the LDCs. If financing for a term of 10-12 years and at a 12- 14 percent interest rate is available to EGAS/EGPC, financing new connections of higher-volume consumers would be an attractive option. The GoE may wish to investigate external financing such as a World Bank loan. On an LE equivalent basis, a World Bank loan, which can be as long as 20 years, should be attractive for conversions of households of all but the lowest gas consumers (unless there is an aggregation between lower- and higher-volume gas consumers). · Are there other factors to consider between LDC and EGAS/EGPC financing of the Household Connection Fee? Financing of connections by the LDCs in the Egyptian commercial banking market would depend in large part on the expectation that the LDC would recover its capital costs through rates paid by EGAS/EGPC, and, consequently, on the creditworthiness of EGAS/EGPC. The obligation of EGAS/EGPC to make these payments constitutes a 40 direct liability of EGAS/EGPC, and would need to be recorded as such. If EGAS/EGPC were to document its obligation with an assignable guarantee of its liability, it would greatly facilitate LDC financing. It is debatable whether the addition of a GoE guarantee of EGAS/EGPC's payment obligations to the LDCs would increase the liabilities of the sovereign, given the close relationship between GoE and EGAS/EGPC, although such a guarantee certainly would facilitate LDC financing if it were assignable to lenders. Whether financing of new connections is arranged as direct borrowing by GoE or of a borrowing by LDC enhanced by a GoE guarantee, such financing would constitute a direct liability of the sovereign. The GoE should explore with potential lenders the possibility of only a partial guarantee of the LDCs' repayment obligations to the lenders, rather than a full guarantee of EGAS/EGPC's capital recovery payments. Such a partial credit guarantee might, for example, guarantee only later principal repayments so as to motivate lenders to lend for a longer term. This might reduce the sovereign liability to half or less (present value) of the loan amount. A guarantee by the GoE may provide benefits that are less obvious, as well. The involvement of private financiers, particularly private Egyptian commercial banks, will necessarily impose commercial behavior on the LDCs. Putting the LDCs at risk for cost overruns and construction delays will encourage efficiency in the procurement of new connections of potential natural gas customers. Six million new connections represent a very large amount of financing. Another potential advantage of LDC financing supported by a GoE guarantee is the opportunity to reduce GoE involvement in the financing over time. If, in fact, the involvement of private financiers and the provision of only a partial guarantee by the GoE has the effect of imposing commercial discipline on the LDCs, presumably the LDCs should, over time, become able to support financing of new connections on the basis of their own credit, reducing or eliminating the need for GoE guarantees. Based on the above assumptions, it was demonstrated that it is economically viable to develop the natural gas distribution network for middle- and higher-volume households in Egypt. Although low-volume households are not attractive by themselves to convert due to their limited volume uptake, by targeting areas with a combination of income groups and possibly commercial customers, it should be possible to convert all income groups economically. 41 The Global Partnership on Output-Based Aid About the GPOBA Working Paper series: The GPOBA Working Paper Series is a forum intended to be a relatively informal and for presenting topics related to output-based efficient way to discuss relevant OBA design aid approaches that may help in enhancing issues. The conclusions presented in each the design of future OBA projects. The series working paper are those conclusions of the will focus on the infrastructure and social authors, and do not necessarily represent the services sectors, but may also include papers views of GPOBA or its donors. that are non-sector specific. The forum is Global Partnership on Output Based Aid World Bank To find out more, visit Mailstop: H3-300 Washington, DC 20433, USA www.gpoba.org Supporting the delivery of basic services in developing countries Back Sheet 4-24-0 1 4/24/06, 9:52 AM