Report No. 22953-IRN Iran Trade and Foreign Exchange Policies in Iran Reform Agenda, Economic Implications and Impact on the Poor November 1, 2001 Social and Economic Development Group Middle East and North Africa Region Document of the World Bank Currency Equivalents Currency Unit = Iranian Rial (Rls) Official Exchange Rate: US$1 = Rls 1,750 Tehran Stock Exchange Rate (TSE): US$1 = Rls 7,970 Iranian Fiscal Years end March 20 Princinal Abbreviations and Acronyms Used CAS Country Assistance Strategy GDP Gross Domestic Product DFI Foreign Direct Investment EDBI Export Development Bank of Iran EPZ Export Processing Zones FTZ Free Trade Zone FYDP Five-Year Development Plan IBRD International Bank for Reconstruction and Development 10 input-output LIBOR London Interbank Offered Rate ISIRI Institute of Standards and Industrial Research of Iran MENA Middle East and Norht Africa MPO Management and Plan Organization NTB Non-Tariffs Barriers RIs Iranian Rials TSE Tehran Stock Exchange WBI World Bank Institute WTO World Trade Organization This report was based on a mission to Iran in October and November 2000 led by Habib Fetini (Middle East and North Africa, Social and Economic Development Group). The report was written under the direction of David Tarr (Development Economics Research Group). The team included George Fane (consultant); Dorsati Madani (Poverty Reduction and Economic Management Network, Economic Policy Division); Jesper Jensen (consultant); Krisztina Mazo and Alexandra Sperling (Middle East and North Africa, Social and Economic Development Group) were responsible for the processing of the report. The team wishes to thank numerous government agencies and organizations in Iran who provided advice and support including: the Ministry of Finance, Ministry of Commerce, Central Bank, Customs Department, Export Development Bank of Iran, Export Guarantee Fund of Iran, Ministry of Industry and Mining. The mission was hosted by the Institute for Trade Studies and Research, to its Management and Staff goes our sincere gratitude for their skillful help and their hospitality. The team gratefully acknowledges the support provided by the government of the United Kingdom, Department for International Development, through a trust fund established with the Development Economics Research Group. Vice President: Jean-Louis Sarbib Director: Mustapha K. Nabli Task Team Leader: David Tarr CONTENTS List of Tables, Figures and Boxes ......................................................................... iii Executive Summary ......................................................................... iv 1. The Need for Reform and the Government's Reform Agenda .............................................................1 1.1 The Case for Lowering Barriers to Trade: Iran's High Barriers Reduce Growth ......................................1 1.2 Earlier Efforts at Reform in Iran .........................................................................3 1.3 The Government's Current Reform Agenda ............................. .............................................4 2. Iran's Import Regime ..............5................................................5 2.1 Import Licensing Regulations .........................................................................5 2.2 Quantifying Tariff and Nontariff Barriers to Imports .......................................................................... 9 The Magnitude of Iran's Explicit Taxes on Imports .......................................................................... 9 The Magnitude of Iran's Nontariff Barriers to Imports ......................................................................... 11 Trade Taxes and Subsidies Implicit in the Dual Exchange Rate System .............. .................................. 13 2.3 Other Indirect and Direct Taxes ......................................................................... 14 Sales Taxes ......................................................................... 14 Direct Taxes ......................................................................... 15 2.4 Policy Recommendations ......................................................................... 16 3. Foreign Exchange Markets in Iran ............................................................. 18 3.1 The Current System of Multiple Exchange Rates .......................................................... ............... 18 3.2 The Tehran Stock Exchange Market for Foreign Exchange and the "Negotiated" Rate ......................... 19 The Tehran Stock Exchange Market and the "Export" Rate .................................................................... 19 The Negotiated Rate ..................................................................... . .. 20 3.3 The Government's Foreign Exchange Budget .................................... ..................................... 20 3.4 Policy Recommendations ......................................................................... 22 4. Iran's Export Regime ............................................................. 23 4.1 Checks and Controls on Exports ......................................................................... 23 Export Licensing and Bans ......................................................................... 23 Surrender of Foreign Exchange ......................................................................... 25 Compulsory Export Quality Standards ......................................................................... 26 4.2 Duty-Free Access to Inputs by Exporters ......................................................................... 28 Drawbacks and Exemptions ......................................................................... 29 Free-Trade Zones ......................................................................... 32 Special Economic Zones ......................................................................... 35 4.3 Export Finance, Insurance, and Guarantees ............................. ............................................ 37 The Export Development Bank of Iran ......................................................................... 37 The Export Guarantee Fund of Iran ......................................................................... 39 4.4 Policy Recommendations .............................................. . ......................... 40 Eliminating Exchange Controls ......................................................................... 40 Setting Export Quality Standards and Technical Regulations on Imports ................... ............................ 40 Improving Duty Drawbacks and Exemptions ......................................................................... 40 Reducing the Distortions Caused by Export Credits, Guarantees, and Insurance ................................... 41 Developing a New Strategy for the Free-Trade and Special Economic Zones ......................................... 42 Annex 4A. Iran's Free-Trade Zones: Kish, Qeshm, and Chahbahar .................................... ........................ 43 5. Quantifying the Gains from Trade and Exchange Rate Reform in Iran ........................................... 47 5.1. Data on Tariffs, Nontariff Barriers, and Subsidies ......................................................................... 47 Data on Tariffs ......................................................................... 47 Tariff Equivalence of Nontariff Barriers ......................................................................... 49 Data on Centrally Allocated Foreign Exchange ......................................................................... 50 5.2. The Model ......................................................................... 51 5.3. Results and Policy Implications ................................................ 56 Tariffying Nontariff Barriers .................................................. 57 Unifying the Exchange Rate .................................................. 60 Lowering Tariffs and Introducing Competition .................................................. 62 Setting a Uniform Tariff of 15 Percent ....................... ........................... 63 Adopting Integrated Pricing Reforms .................................................. 63 Reforming Petroleum Prices .................................................. 66 Combining Trade and Exchange Rate Reform ........................................ . ........ 66 Combining Energy and Exchange Rate Reform ........................................ . ........ 66 Combining Trade, Energy, and Exchange Rate Reform .................................................. 66 Annex SA. Data and Model Construction ................................................ 68 Annex Sb: Compensating The Poor For The Removal Of ............ .............................. . .... 70 Price Subsidies On The Consumption Of Essential Goods ............ .............................. . .... 70 6. Sequencing Reforms ........................................... 72 Appendix: Trade Data for Iran ........................................... 75 References ........................................... 79 ii LIST OF TABLES, FIGURES AND BOXES Tables Table 1. Estimated Gains from Reform (percent of consumption) . ......................................................................... vii Table 1.1 Average Unweighted Tariff Rates for Countries with Highest Tariffs and Selected Other Countries, 1996-98 ...................................................................................2 Table 2. Recommended Sequencing of Reforms .............................. .................................................... xi Table 2.1. The Positive List ...................................................................................5 Table 2.2. Average Collected Import Tax Rates, 1999-2000 .................................................................................. 10 Table 2.3. Estimated Unweighted Average Rates of the Commercial Benefit Tax Needed to Compensate Producers for Tariffication of Items Subject to Ministry of Industry Licensing Requirements ................................. 12 Table 2.4. Estimated Minimum and Maximum Rates of the Commercial Benefit Tax Needed to Compensate Producers for Tariffication of Items Subject to Ministry of Industry Licensing Requirements ........ ....... 13 Table 3.1 Oil Revenues at Various Exchange Rates, 1995/96-1999/2000 ................................................................. 21 Table 4.1 Banned Exports and Exports Requiring Permits Issued by the Ministry of Commerce in 1998/99 ........ 24 Table 4.2 Exports Requiring Permits in 1999/2000 .................................................................................. 25 Table 4.3 Policies in Iran's Free-Trade and Special Economic Zones ................................... ................................. 36 Table 4.4. EDBI Loans by Industrial Sector, 1992/93 and 1998/99 .................................................38...............I...... 38 Table 4A. 1. Performance of the Kish Free-Trade Zone, 1998-99 ............................................................................. 43 Table 4A.2. Performance of the Qeshm Special Economic Zone, 1993 and 1998 . . 45 Table 5.1. Import Protection of Sectors Included in the Model .................................................................................. 48 Table 5.2 Expenditure Shares by Household Type .................................................................................. 56 Table 5.3. Impact of Trade and Exchange Rate Reforms: Welfare and Macroeconomic Effects ............................... 58 Table 5.4. Impact of Trade and Exchange Rate Reforms on Domestic Output, Prices, and Exports by Sector... ...... 59 Table 5.5. Impact of Trade, Exchange Rate, and Energy Pricing Reforms ........................... .................................... 64 Table 5.6. Impact of Trade, Exchange Rate, and Energy Pricing Reforms on Domestic Output, Prices, and Exports by Sector .................................................................................. 65 Table SAI. Estimated Domestic and International Prices for Petroleum Products, 1999/2000 .................................. 69 Table Al. Iranian Exports by Major Partner, 1989-99 .75 Table A2. Iranian Imports by Major Partner, 1989-99 .76 Table A3. Iranian Export Structure and Major Products, 1989-99 .77 Table A4. Iranian Import Structure and Major Products, 1989-99 .78 Figures Figure 5.1 Production and Allocation of Output in Iran ......................................................... 52 Figure 5.2 Crude Oil Production and Allocation in Iran ......................................................... 53 Figure 5.3 Energy Sectors Production and Allocation in Iran ......................................................... 54 Figure 5.4 Consumer Demand in Iran .......................................................... 55 Box Box 4.1. Increasing Export and Employment through Free Trade Zones FTZs ........................................................ 32 iii EXECUTIVE SUMMARY This report describes Iran's trade and exchange rate policies, proposes and expl;ins a reform program, and develops a computable general equilibrium of fran's economy to estimate the gains -to the economy as a whole and to the poor-likely to accrue from various reform options. Thie report also recommends a program for sequencing the reforms. Government Domination of the Economy and the Retreat from Economic Reform For the past two decades, Iran's economy has been dominated by the government. During this period overall economic performance has been disappointing. Per capita GDP was 16 percent lower in 1998 than in 1979, and inflation averaged 20 percent a year over the two-decade period (II4F 2000). In the decade between 1988 and 1998, per capita GDP growth was at least positive, but averaged just 3 percent a year. The government began to liberalize its economic policies during the First Five-Year Development Plan (1990191-1994/95), under which GDP growth rose to an average annual rate of 6 percent. Faced with the slump in oil prices in the mid-1990s, the U.S. embargo on trade and investment, the bunching of scheduled debt repayments, and the inability to obtain new foreign financing, however, the government interrupted the reforms. In response to the fall in foreign exchange receipts, it tightened import licensing controls and allowed the rial to become increasingly overvalued at the official exchange rale. Queues for foreign exchange developed, the premium of the open market exchange rate over the official rate increased dramatically, the annual inflation rate rose to 19 percent in the period 1989--94 and to 40 percent in 1994-95, and annual GDP growth slowed to 4 percent in the period 1994-98. Progress on Reform and the Government's Current Reform Agenda The election of President Khatami in 1997 strengthened the reform movement and allowed Iran to improve its relations with the rest of the world. The upturn in world oil prices that begaun in 2000 has allowed Iran to reduce its foreign debts and reinitiate a reform program. These developmenms have helped the government make very substantial progress toward reform in the past three years. In 2000 arrears on official debts were cleared, and foreign exchange reserves rose substantially. The macroeconomic situation has been stabilized, and both the fiscal balance and the balance on the current a.ccount of the balance payments are positive. In addition, significant trade and foreign exchange refor:ns have been implemented: 1. Substantial progress has been made toward eventually unifying Iran's multiple exchange rates. The multiple exchange rate system now operates mainly as a way of subsidizing imports of "essential" goods, prices of which are controlled. 2. Many nontariff barriers on imports have been replaced by their tariff equivalents. Restrictive import licensing requirements required by the Ministry of Industry were lifted on 781 produc:s during 2000. Another 114 items were exempted from the restrictive licensing requirements of other line ministries, bringing to 895 the total number of items from which nontariff barriers have been removed. At the same time, import taxes on many of these items were increased in an attempt to compensate domestic producers for loss of protection. As of October 2000 no restrictive licensing conditions applied to 2,795 of the 5,113 six-digit Harmonized System of product codes used in Iran. iv 3. Import licensing requirements have also been eased by expanding the "positive list" of items that can be imported relatively easily by firms that earn their foreign exchange by exporting or that buy foreign exchange on the Tehran Stock Exchange. At the time of the foreign exchange crisis of 1998/99, the positive list included just 31 broad categories of importable items. By early 2000 it contained 41 items, and the number was raised to 77 in November 2000. 4. Licensing restrictions on exports have been eased. 5. Customs procedures for both imports and exports have been simplified and delays reduced. 6. Many redundant compulsory export standards have been eliminated. 7. Exporters have been given improved access to imported inputs at world prices. The government has used duty drawback and temporary exemption schemes, free-trade and special economic zones, and export finance agencies to encourage exporters, albeit with limited success. 8. Part of the anti-trade bias of the indirect tax system has been removed by raising the sales tax rates on some domestic products to approximate parity with those on the corresponding imported products. When a value-added tax is introduced, the remaining anti-trade bias of the indirect tax system will be completely removed. The govemment has already made significant progress in implementing trade and foreign exchange reforms, but it intends to do much more. The ambitious plan of reform outlined in the Third Five-Year Development Plan (2000/01-2004/05) calls for unifying the multiple exchange rate system and abolishing exchange controls on the current account, removing nontariff barriers to trade and gradually reducing tariffs, and encouraging the growth of nontraditional exports. International experience suggests that these reforms will benefit most Iranians and help the poor if appropriately targeted. They will also help Iran gain membership in the World Trade Organization (WTO). Estimating the Benefits of Reform Changes in trade and foreign exchange policy affect both the economy as a whole and the poor as a group. To estimate the effects on both groups, we develop a multisector computable general equilibrium model of the Iranian economy. The estimated welfare gains from adopting trade and foreign exchange reforms in Iran are extremely large (table 1). Constant returns to scale numerical modeling estimates have often found that trade liberalization increases the welfare of a country by only about 0.5-1.0 percent of GDP. In contrast, in Iran we find welfare gains of as much as 50 percent of household consumption or about 19 percent of total GDP.' These very large estimated gains reflect the unusually high level of distortions at the starting point of the reform. Our results also indicate that the proposed reforms are pro-poor. In addition, all the reforms discussed in this report generate revenue for the government. As summnarized in table 1, we estimate that the government's budget surplus will increase by 1.4 percent of GDP from tariffication of non-tariff barriers alone, by 5.3% of GDP from removal of foreign exchange subsidies alone, and by 13.3 percent of GDP from removal of energy subsidies alone. 1 Household consumption is about 37 percent of GDP. Unless otherwise noted, we report estimates as a percent of household consumption, rather than a percent of GDP. Welfare results as a percent of GDP are therefore 37 percent of the values reported as a percent of household consumption. v Tariffying nontariff barriers increases aggregate welfare and helps the poor Based primarily on Ministry of Industry estimates, we estimate that the tariff equivalence of nontariff barriers in Iran is about 17 percent of the value of imports. Assuming that thc rents from nontariff barriers are dissipated through rent-seeking, we estimate that tariffication of nontariff barriers will lead to an increase in aggregate welfare of 3.4 percent of the value of household consumption in the benchmark equilibrium. This gain in welfare is generated from the reallocation of the resources wasted on obtaining import licenses. The impact on the poor is strongly affected by what the government does with the additional revenue it receives. We assume that the government distributes the additional revenue it receives back to households in equal amounts. Even though the poor are not targeted by this distribution mechanism, the poor will gain substantially from this policy reform. Because they have such small incomes, even small transfers can represent a significant portion of the income of the poorest households. In fact the income of the poorest rural household type is estimated to rise 23 percent, while that of the poorest urban household type is estimated to increase 11 percent. Setting a uniform tariff rate of 15 percent helps the poor more than setting a maximum tariff rate of 25 percent Both setting a maximum tariff rate of 25 percent and establishing a uniform tariff rate c of 15 percent result in significant increases in welfare, but the poor gain much more from uniform tariffs. The uniform policy helps the poor more because it generates greater revenue for the government. Lowering tariffs to 15 percent or less is also likely to be a requirement for admission to the WTO. The favorable experience of other developing countries with uniform, or near uniform, tariffs is summarized in section '2.4. Eliminating foreign exchange subsidies disproportionately helps the poor, especially if the gains are distributed as lump-sum payments Subsidies to foreign exchange represent more than 6 percent of Iran's GDP. We estimate that eliminating these subsidies and distributing the gain as lump-sum payments would increase aggregate welfare by 6.9 percent of consumption. Moreover, although some of the subsidies for purchases of imports are intended to assist the poor, it is the poor who would disproportionately gain from i his policy. If instead of distributing the gain as lump-sum payments the govemment were to provide consumption subsidies for essential commodities, the welfare gain to the poor would be slightly lower (6.7 percent). More interestingly, the welfare gains to the poor would be much lower (46 percent of the value of consumption instead of the 72 percent gained under a lump-sum payment). These results show that well-intentioned policies for the poor can have perverse effects. Even though the direct income payments we consider are not targeted at the poor, they do a better job of improving the welfare of the poor than commodity subsidies, which are perceived to target the poor. As a practical matter, efficient safety mechanisms for the poor are difficult to implement. The World Bank and the government of Iran have agreed to a followup study on the efficient distribution of the fiscal surplus from subsidy reduction and tariffication of non-tariff barriers. The mechanism we assume, however, does allow us to assess and quantify the distributional consequences, including on the poor, of the existing pattern of subsidies and licenses. vi Combining trade and exchange rate reform results in a welfare gain equal to more than 12 percent of consumption Tariffying nontariff barriers, unifying the exchange rate, and setting a uniform tariff rate of 15 percent yields a combined welfare gain of 12.3 percent of consumption. If tariffs are completely eliminated, the welfare gain rises to 12.7 percent of consumption. The poor gain enormously from these combined policies but, interestingly, they gain more from the 15 percent uniform tariff than the zero tariff, which leaves less fiscal surplus to distribute. Eliminating petroleum subsidies doubles or triples the incomes of the poorest household types Petroleum prices in Iran are only about 10 percent of world prices, and subsidies on petroleum products cost the government an estimated 18 percent of GDP. If the fiscal surplus from eliminating the petroleum product subsidies is transferred back to households in equal amounts, the income of the poorest urban household type doubles, while that of poorest rural household type increases by more than 200 percent. Adopting both energy and exchange rate reform yields even larger gains. Under this strategy, the income of the poorest urban household type rises 116 percent, while that of poorest rural household type rises 239 percent. All households gain, but the percentage gains decrease with the income level of the household. Combining trade, energy, and exchange rate reform generates the largest welfare gains The largest welfare gains accrue from adopting tariffication, tariff reduction, exchange rate unification, and energy pricing reform. Under this scenario, the gain to the Iranian economy is estimated at about 50 percent of the value of consumption following the combined reforms. Table 1. Estimated Gains from Reform (percent of consumption) Marginal Total rise in real Total increase in real income due Change in rise in real income due to to all steps up to and including this Government income due all steps up to onea Fiscal Surplus from Policy step to this and including Poorest rural Poorest urban this Policy Step (% policy step this one household type household type of GDP) Tariffication of nontariff 3.4 3.4 23.3 11.1 1.4 barriers Reduction of tariffs to 25 0.7 4.1 15.6 8.3 0.7 percent Reduction of maximum 1.4 5.5 20.2 10.9 1.0 tariff from 25 percent to 15 percent [ Removal of exchange rate 5.3 subsidies to "essential" 6.9 14.0 95.6 44.3 imports Removal of fuel subsidies 32.9 50.1 292.2 143.1 13.3 Source: Authors' estimates. vii Suggestions and Recommendations Our analysis of Iranian trade and foreign exchange policy suggests that the govermment could increase the welfare of the nation as a whole while improving the relative welfare of the poor by adopting the following reforms: Replacing nontariff barriers by equivalent tariffs and reducing tariffs * We strongly support the government's policy of replacing nontariff barriers by their tariff equivalents. Once all restrictive import licensing conditions have been removed for almost all goods other than those banned for noneconomic reasons, there will be no need for any list of goods that may or may not be imported using a particular source of foreign exchange Moreover, we recommend continued efforts by the government to remove non-tariff barriers Ln technical regulations on goods and sanitary and phytosanitary standards on agricultural imports. The economy will benefit over the long-term with continued movement toward regulatory regimes which are centered on streamnlined requirements, including acceptance of manufacturers declarations of conformity to import requirements in all but the most sensitive areas of health, safety, or environmental regulations. * The static inefficiencies caused by high trade barriers and the cross-country evidence that openness promotes economic growth suggest that reducing import taxes, rather than merely replacing nontariff barriers by their import tax equivalents, makes sense. We recommend that the government aim at achieving a uniform tariff of 15 percent by 2005-with an eye. perhaps, to eventually abolishing tariffs altogether. * In Annex 5A, we explain how a system to compensate the poor for the removal of price subsidies on the consumption of essential commodities can be implemented, based on the system Iran has in place for the distribution of ration coupons for edible oils, sugar and cheese. Reforming taxation * We strongly support the government's plans to replace the current system of pieceme al and anti- trade biased sales taxes by a trade-neutral value-added tax. * We do not support the current policy of granting income tax exemptions to income earned from exporting. Eliminating fuel subsidies The substantial subsidies provided for fuel in Iran place a burden on the fiscal budget and introduce serious distortions into the economy. For these reasons, the government may want to continue eliminating these subsidies. Unifying the exchange rate We strongly support the government's plans to unify the multiple exchange rates. P'rovided that alternative ways of compensating the poor can be devised and administered, there is also a case for removing subsidies on the consumption of items currently imported at the official exchange rate. Making viii recommendations on how best to help the poor is outside the scope of a review of trade policy, however, and should be dealt with by specialists on the design of social safety nets. Promoting exports and reducing anti-export bias Iran's duty drawback and exemption schemes mitigate some of the adverse effects of its import barriers. So too do its free-trade and special economic zones. We therefore support these programs, but suggest ways in which they might be improved. * Drawhacks and exemptikns. To improve the system of duty drawbacks and exemptions, the authorities could consider setting up a specialized unit within the Customs Department to administer both schemes. They could also reduce the period within which exporters can claim duty drawbacks to three months after export and require all firms that receive exemptions from duties on imports to be used as inputs into exports to place bank guarantees for the full amount of the duty, but no more. * Free-trade and s,pecia economic zones. To achieve its aim of transforming the free-trade and special economic zones from import-processing zones into true free-trade zones, the government could accompany reductions in the economywide barriers to imports from foreign countries with the abolition of the preferential treatment of imports into the customs territory of Iran from the free-trade zones and special economic zones. Specifically, it could abolish the $80 allowance of duty-free imports from the free-trade zones for domestic shoppers and reform the "value-added rule," which currently allows limited amounts of duty-free imports from the zones to the mainland. Exports from the zones to the mainland should be subject to the same regulations and duties that apply to imports from foreign countries. The government could also speed up the administrative procedures for approving requests by investors to shift funds into or out of the zones. * Export credits, guaraantees, alnd insurance. In our view, there is no good economic case for preserving, let alone increasing, Iran's subsidies to export finance. Such schemes are used by almost all countries around the world to subsidize manufactured exports, however, and it appears almost inevitable that they will be retained in Iran. To improve the functioning of these mechanisms, the government could ensure that the amount and form of the subsidies provided by the Export Guarantee Fund of Iran and the Export Development Bank of Iran are consistent with the limits on export finance subsidies contained in the WTO's Agreement on Subsidies and Countervailing Measures and in the conventions of the Berne Union. It could also allow other financial institutions to engage in export finance on whatever terms they choose by deregulating lending to exports. The proportion of each bank's loans that must be allocated to export lending could also be deregulated, thus allowing banks to lend as much, or as little, as they wish. a Compulsory export slandardzs. We support the government's plan to adopt a system for product standards that covers health and safety issues but steps back from attempts at full export quality control. The standards system should rely upon market-driven and private sector-led product and process standards. Firms should lead in design and implementation of these voluntary standards. The competitive forces of international market competition will drive quality improvements over time. Sequencing Reforms Announcing a credible plan for reform would help minimize uncertainty. The Third Five-Year Development Plan represents an excellent step in this direction, but still more information is required. The abrupt removal of subsidies to "essential imports" and of protection of domestic manufacturers of most ix other imports may cause dislocations to existing firms, particularly state-owned enterprises, and perhaps raise the already high level of unemployment. To avert such consequences, we recommend a gradual sequencing of reforms, based on the following guidelines (table 2): * During the first two years of the reform program, the government could adopt export promotion measures. * The government could aim to complete the process of transforming nontariff barriers into their tariff equivalents and unify exchange rates by March 2002. * It could aim to phase out partial compensation for the loss of subsidies to "essential imports" (those previously imported at the official exchange rate), apply a uniform tariff rate of 15 percent on all items, and eliminate fuel subsidies by March 2005. Once a low uniform tariff has been achieved, the government could replace the existing commercial benefit tax and customs duties by a tariff at the new rate. x Table 2. Recommended Sequencing of Reforms Date Duty drawbacks, temporary reform admissions, and free-trade and Additional export completed Exchange rate Nontariff barriers Trade taxes special economic zones facilitation measures Fuel subsidies September Eliminate nontariff Raise commercial benefit Announce reform of free-trade and Align Export Convert all 2001 barriers on at least half tax on all items that are special economic zones, including Guarantee Fund oil revenues at Tehran of all six-digit tariffied (about 2,000 the elimination of the tourist programs and Stock Exchange rate. harmonized system harmonized system codes) shopping allowance and the incentive schemes of code items. to compensate for realignment of export policy with the Export Retain real fuel subsidy removing nontariff that of the mainland through a Development Bank rates, but include them barriers. national trade policy reform, which with WTO Agreement explicitly in the budget. would take effect the following on Subsidies and March. Countervailing Measures and Berne Create a special unit in the agreements. Customs Department for handling duty drawback and temporary Continue to move admissions of imported items for toward standards re-export or for use as inputs into which are private exports. sector developed and remove government Reduce duty drawback claim controls. Institute period from three to two years; system for technical reduce export claim period to a regulations and SPS maximum of three months; reduce measures over imports temporary admission collateral which removes requirements to international norm. discriminatory, duplicative requirements. March Unify all Complete process of Reduce commercial benefit Reform free-trade and special Continue to move Raise domestic fuel 2002 exchange rates at tariffication of tax across the board by economic zones policy incentives toward standards prices to at least 40 managed floating nontariff barriers, enough to leave total by eliminating tourist allowance requirement based on percent of world prices. rate (the Tehran subject to exceptions effective trade taxes and realigning exports to mainland health and safety. Stock Exchange on religious and unchanged when imports with national trade policy reform. or the negotiated national heritage are valued at the Tehran rate). grounds and a few Stock Exchange rate for Perform cost-benefit analysis of special economic tax purposes. Reduce port and electricity plant for Kish Bring existing cases. maximum trade tax rate to and Qeshm. Date Duty drawbacks, temporary reform admissions, andfree-trade and Additional export completed Exchange rate Nontariff barriers Trade taxes special economic zones facilitation measures Fuel subsidies implicit subsidies 100 percent and average Pursue implementing Automated to debt repayment, rate to 30 percent. System of Customs Data. defense, essential imports, and infrastructure projects on- budget. March Reduce subsidies Reduce average tariff to 25 Raise fuel prices to 60 2003 to debt repayment percent, with a maximum percent of world prices. to 50 percent. tariff of 60 percent. March Reduce subsidies Reduce the average tariff Raise fuel prices to 80 2004 to debt repayment to 20 percent, with a percent of world prices. to 25 percent. maximum tariff of 40 percent. March Eliminate Unify all import duties at Remove all remaining 2005 remaining 15 percent. Replace fuel subsidies. subsidies to debt commercial benefit tax and repayment. customs duty by a single Maintain managed import tariff. floating exchange rate. xii 1. THE NEED FOR REFORM AND THE GOVERNMENT'S REFORM AGENDA 1) Iran's economic performance in the last two decades has been very disappointing. This is highlighted by the fact that per capita GDP was 16 percent lower in 1998 than in 1979. However, the most import single reason for this poor performance was not any domestic economic policy, but the long and costly war with Iraq. Fluctuations in oil prices and the US embargo also adversely affected the economy. Once the war with Iraq had finished, economic performance began to improve slowly; in the decade ending in 1998 per capita GDP growth was positive, although it averaged only 3 percent per year. Although less important than the war with Iraq, Iran's domestic economic policies have not been conducive to rapid economic growth. Economic performance has been and still is hampered by administered prices; large, poorly targeted subsidies; multiple exchange rates (which remain important, despite recent progress in reducing disparities among them); trade restrictions; and state domination of economic activity. All banks in Iran are state owned, and most large firms are owned by the state or by the quasi-public religious foundations (bonyads). 2) The government tried to liberalize the economy during the First Five-Year Development Plan (1990/91-1994/95), but its plans collapsed under the pressures of a fall in oil prices, the U.S. embargo on trade and investment, and a tight debt repayment schedule. Instead of adopting a policy of fiscal and monetary restraint, the government imposed nontariff barriers on imports, tightened exchange controls, and expanded domestic credit. The result was stagnation, inflation, and a debt crisis. 1.1 The Case for Lowering Barriers to Trade: Iran's High Barriers Reduce Growth 3) Iran's nontariff barriers are much higher and more pervasive than those of most other developing countries. One study of 43 developing countries for which data were available for the period 1995-98 found that restrictive licensing conditions applied to just 10 percent of imports and prohibitions applied to another 2 percent (Michalopoulos 1999).2 In contrast, even after the October 2000 replacement of many nontariff barriers by their tariff equivalents, restrictive licensing conditions still applied to 45 percent of six-digit harmonized system codes in Iran. Of the 43 countries in Michalopoulos's data set, only India (at 94 percent) had more pervasive import licensing. 4) The unweighted economywide average of the tariff equivalents of Iran's existing tariff and nontariff barriers is about 30 percent, according to the estimates we present in the next section. Between 1996 and 1998 only 7 of 150 developing and industrial countries for which estimates of average tariffs were available for at least one of the years 1996-98 had average tariffs than exceeded 30 percent (table 1.1). Of course, a much larger number of countries may have had combined tariffs and nontariff baffiers that exceeded 30 percent. Nevertheless, since nontariff barriers have fallen greatly in many developing countries in the past decade and average tariffs in most countries have fallen further since 1996-98, these data suggest that Iran has one of the highest rates of protection in the world.3 5) Historical experience conclusively demonstrates the massive economic costs of all-encompassing govemment intervention in economic affairs. The period since World War II provides several examples 2 Nontariff barrier coverage in Michalopoulos's study is measured as the proportion of two-digit harmonized system codes to which nontariff barriers apply. 3Michalopoulos (1999) argues that following the 1994 Uruguay Round Agreements, the use of nonautomatic licensing, quotas, tariff quotas, voluntary export restraints and price control measures such as variable charges, minimum prices, and voluntary export price restraints is at its lowest level in more than 50 years. of pairs of countries that began with similar living standards, factor endowments, institutions, and cultures and which, as a result of historical accidents over which they had no control, chose radically different economic strategies (Hungary and Austria, the German Democratic Republic and the Federal Republic of Germany, the Republic of Korea and the Democratic People's Republic of Korea). These comparisons come very close to meeting the conditions for controlled experiments in the natural sciences and remove all reasonable doubt over the fact that countries with relatively free market economies outperlfOrm those in which the state exercises rigid control over the economy. Table 1.1 Average Unweighted Tariff Rates for Countries with Highest Tariffs and Selecited Other Countries, 1996-98 (percent) Countrv 1990 1996 1997 1998 Average 1996-98 Countries with average tariffs of more t an 30 percentt Pakistan 64.8 41.7 -- 41.7 Morocco -- -- 36.7 _ 36.7 Cambodia -- 35.0 -- -- 35.0 India 81.8 38.7 35.0 30.0 34.6 Bahamas -- 32.0 32.0 Burkina Faso _ 32.2 32.2 31.1 31.8 Egypt -- 35.5 26.8 31.2 Selected other countries _ _-- -- -- Algeria -- - -- 24.2 24.2 Argentina 20.5 11.2 11.3 13.5 12.0 Brazil 32.2 -- 11.8 14.6 13.2 Chile 15.0 -- 11.0 11.0 11.0 China 40.3 23.6 17.6 17.5 19.6 Indonesia 20.6 13.2 -- 9.5 11.4 Malaysia -- 8.7 9.1 - 8.9 Mexico 11.1 12.6 12.6 13.3 12.8 Nigeria 35.7 -- 24.4 23.4 23.9 Philippines 27.8 14.3 13.4 10.7 12.8 Saudi Arabia -- 13.0 -- -- 13.0 South Africa 11.0 8.8 8.7 5.6 7.7 Thailand 39.8 -- -- 20.1 20.1 Tunisia 27.41 -- 29.9 29.9 Turkey -- - 13.5 12.7 13.1 Average developing country (n =127) 32.9 18.6 17.0 17.5 13.8 Average industrial country (n = 23) 7.9 5.3 5.0 4.4 4.9 -- Not available. Note: All tariff rates are based on unweighted averages for all goods in ad valorem, or applied. rates, or most favorcd nation rates, whichever data were available for a longer period. The full data set (available at http://www .worldbank.org/wbiep/trade/TR Data.html) contains 150 countries. Source: WTO, IDB CD ROM database and Trade Policy Review - Country Report, Various issues, 1990-2000; U.i (>< >£XNoooXofiX~qqr> x i°lS ° W o b b ,w b ° w ° ° ° ° ° < 0\ u XOD v A ° ° 9s - k A4 71 % 3 ~~~~~~~~~~~~...... ... .. .. . ........ ... ... ... ... . . ............................. ............. . ........ ... . ................................ ........ .............. ........... . . .............. .. . . ....... ... .. ............... . .............................. .................. o x >X > h w 8 9 o ; J sO X 9> o w utiw ox s > ° w w wo x o w > W° O4°o s -o U _~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~O _ W*_ 'O i, L4rk ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ 0 9 P Pt P 9 P Ps P P P P °h P z94°°o>W o wxt 55 gWS oooS goSo o S --<~0 £ OWoX>>oo 41 -~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~- 00P 0- 40 0 -00 0 00 - - . 00P- " 00-P0 0P 0 _ ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~. _.. .................. ...... .. ........ ............... ...... ........ ... ......... ....... ... . .. .............. . ................. ...... ... ...................... ......... .... ................ ................. 00A 0A004-4000-40.OA.00.0'0 4 (.4 00000000o -£xb£ 'xx0x00000x 00=40-400 t.>o> °a ,x 4is os>i vwO£wgw£> wo x w vgOgAoe h 6£-wo w > eowx . ,k>9 .0.......... - . ... ............ .'0........ . . ...... .. . . ..4.........0..' 0......0.' 00..0 - - ~ ~ ~~~~~~ 04 - - - - 04 - 04 - - - 0 0.4 '0~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~:-91~o91 9 C) M - , - - - 0 179) An interesting and unique aspect of this scenario is that the output of all Iranian industries expands, as real resources that had been allocated to rent-seeking are freed up by tariffication. At the same time, the increase in the supply of labor and capital for production results in a 0.1 percent decline in the real wage and a 0.4 percent decline in the rental rate on capital. These declines are more than offset by the additional output available from the productive use of the newly available capital and labor and the income transfers from the government. 180) The principal impact of the tariffication of nontariff barriers without rent dissipation is the increase in government revenues, which increase by 2.0 percent of GDP (column 2 in table 5.3). Since we assume that the government distributes these gains back to households in equal Iranian rial anmounts, poor households gain substantially, even though rich households lose in this scenario (see the next s,ection for a discussion of the distribution scheme). The distributional impacts are strictly progressive, because we assume that the rents from the quotas were not dissipated but rather accrued to households in proportion to their income. 181) There is a slight negative welfare effect due to the fact that tariffication induces a smrll increase in the food and energy subsidies. Given the change in the distribution of income, expenditure in the economy shifts toward the budget items consumed more intensely by the poorer households. As shown in table 5.2, the poor intensively consume food, energy, and transportation (an intense direct user of energy subsidies). The increased demand for food and energy results in a slight reduction in economywide efficiency and welfare because increased consumption of these products due to subsidies reduces efficiency. 182) The impact of the different policy changes on domestic output, prices and exports at the sector level is presented in tables 5.4 and 5.6. Unifying the Exchange Rate 183) We simulate the unification of the exchange rate (that is, the removal of subsidies through centrally allocated foreign exchange at the official exchange rate for essential commodities and for the investment demands of state-owned enterprises). Because petroleum product consumption subsidies are considered part of energy policy, we retain them, except in the energy policy scenarios. 184) Eliminating subsidized foreign exchange for the investment demand of state-owned enterprises increases efficiency with no obvious impact on the poor, since the owners of capital and labor employed in these enterprises are not likely to be poor. Since the objective of subsidizing foreign e.xchange for essential commodities is to assist the poor, alternate safety net programs need to be promided if the subsidies are removed. We consider two alternate programs that could be designed to address the needs of the poor. 185) First, we assess the impact of distributing the additional revenue the government cibtains from eliminating subsidies back to all households in equal lump-sum payments to each household (column 5 in table 5.3). All households, rather than just poor households, are included because it may be difficult to identify at first which households are poor. As a practical manner, the design and implennentation of social safety nets is difficult. Any scheme which distributes income back to households is subject to fraudulent claims. Some households may collect more than once. More seriously, intermeciiaries may attempt to capture distributions intended for others, possibly excluding some poor households. Over time, 60 excluded households should be able to obtain payments, and it may become possible to accurately identify poor households, at which time safety net payments can be targeted.27 Including all households should minimize the risk that no needy household is excluded. This issue will be analyzed in more detail in a follow-up study as the World Bank and the govemment of Iran have agreed to a study of how to efficiently distribute the surpluses from subsidy reduction and tariffication. 186) The aggregate welfare gain from this policy is a very large 6.9 percent increase of income. The magnitude of the effect shows how inefficient a dual exchange rate regime can be when the market exchange rate is four or five times the official exchange rate and substantial amounts of foreign exchange is allocated at the official rate. 187) The gains are derived from the fact that subsidized foreign exchange means that different sectors face different prices for their imports. Moreover, even the same sector or firm faces different prices for its imports depending on how the foreign exchange is spent (investment demand versus current use of imports as intermediates). This implies that the foreign exchange is inefficiently allocated between sectors and uses. Sectors and uses that receive subsidized foreign exchange value it less highly than those who have to pay the market price for foreign exchange. Unifying the exchange rates will induce purchases so that foreign exchange is valued equally at the margin by all sectors and uses. 188) Once the subsidies are lifted, the prices of essential commodities increase significantly (38 percent for sugar, 11 percent for farm products, 6 percent for food). Despite these price increases, however, the welfare of the poorest households increases significantly. The welfare of the two poorest rural household types rises 72 and 45 percent; the welfare of the two poorest urban household types rises 32 and 20 percent. These increases occur because these households are so poor that the lump-sum distribution payments represent a substantial portion of their income. Note that all individual households gain from this policy but that the distribution scheme is monotonically progressive: the poorer the household, the larger the percentage gain. Thus even though the distribution scheme is not perfectly targeted at the poor, it is highly pro-poor. 189) Import subsidies represent an implicit tax on the farming sector, which has to compete with heavily subsidized imports. Removing subsidies to imports results in an increase in the price of farm products and removes the implicit tax on Iranian farmers. As a result, the price of domestic farm products rises 7 percent and the farming sector grows 13 percent. Similarly, domestic producers of items that competed with subsidized imports (producers of sugar, oils, pharmaceuticals, and industrial machinery) see demand for their products increase and respond with increased production in the new equilibrium. These sectors expand considerably, competing resources away from other sectors. 190) Eliminating subsidies to imports also reduces demand for foreign exchange, causing the real exchange rate to appreciate by an estimated 13 percent. Output effects by sector are also partly explained by this appreciation. 191) An alternate scheme for protecting the poor that is sometimes proposed is subsidizing consumption of essential commodities (column 6 in table 5.3). This subsidy does not discriminate based on the geographic source of the product, thereby removing the implicit tax on domestic producers of the import-competing product and eliminating the distortion in consumer choice between imports and 27 This was the process adopted in Jordan, where food subsidies were initially converted to a payment to all households. Only later were payments targets at the poor. 61 domestically produced goods. It should therefore be welfare superior to an import subsidy (see Bhagwati and Srinivasan 1971). 192) In fact, we observe a substantial aggregate welfare gain from this policy, equal to 6.7 percent of income. Since subsidies to consumption of essential food commodities and pharmaceuticals distort resource allocation toward production and consumption of these commodities, the aggregate welfare gain is slightly less than that generated by the policy of exchange rate unification without subsidies to consumption (6.9 percent), however. 193) By design of the experiment, there is no change in the price of any of the essential commodities. Since all subsidies to foreign exchange (not only those to essential commodities) are eliminaled in this scenario, the net fiscal impact on the government is positive.28 Poor households gain in this scenario but considerably less than they do if the government eliminates foreign exchange subsidies without subsidizing food consumption. The smaller gains to poor households are explained by the fact that the fiscal gains to be distributed back to households are smaller as a result of the subsidization of food consumption. The model helps us understand that a policy designed to help the poor can be counterproductive. Lowering Tariffs and Introducing Competition 194) The government intends to introduce foreign competition in the Iranian marketplace after it has tariffied nontariff barriers. Since the government intends to adopt a gradual approach to tariff liberalization, we simulate a sequential process of lowering tariffs in two steps. In the first step, the government lowers all tariffs above 25 percent to 25 percent, leaving all other tariffs unchanged. In the second step, the government imposes a uniform tariff of 15 percent. Unless otherwise indicated, all simulations are based on a benchmark equilibrium in which rents are dissipated. The simulation combines the effect of tariffying nontariff barriers and lowering tariffs in some sectors. We infer the marginal impact of lowering tariffs as the difference between the gain from both removing nontariff barriers and lowering tariffs and the gain from tarrifying nontariff barriers but leaving tariffs at their current levels. 195) The first simulation examines the case in which tariffs above 25 percent are lowered to 25 percent and nontariff barriers are tariffied (column 3 in table 5.3). Under this scenario, aggregate welfare increases relative to the initial equilibrium by 4.1 percent of real consumer income. The average effective or collected tariff, which is 2.5 percent initially, increases to 19.4 percent. When the maximum tariff is set at 25 percent, the average effective tariff falls to 15.3 percent. 196) Given tariffication of nontariff barriers, the marginal impact of lowering high tariffs to 25 percent maximum is 0.6 percent of real consumer income. By international standards, this is a large gain in welfare for a change in the average tariff rate of this magnitude. It illustrates that the largest gains from trade policy reform are derived from reducing protection to moderate levels in sectors with the very high protection. 197) After tariffication the sectors with the highest tariffs would be clothing (93 percent), textiles (74 percent), weaving and leather products (75 percent), and motor vehicles (37 percent). Reducing these tariffs, well as those on glass and other food products, to 25 percent results in a deprecation of the real 28 There is, however, a net fiscal cost to the government associated with replacing an import subsidy with a consumpti on subsidy for a particular product. 62 exchange rate by 2.5 percent, which induces an increase in exports of 4.5 percent. Three of the four sectors with the highest protection contract, while all other sectors expand. When tariffication is combined with setting a maximum rate of 25 percent, the negative impact on these sectors is muted but still negative. 198) The weaving and leather products sector is interesting, because it will expand despite the lowering of nominal protection, according to our model. This seemingly anomalous result occurs because the depreciation of the real exchange rate increases exports, and the price of imported textile products, which represent 30 percent of the intermediate inputs used in this sector, declines significantly. Setting a Uniform Tariff of 15 Percent 199) Eliminating nontariff barriers and setting a uniform tariff rate of 15 percent (except on petroleum products) results in an increase in aggregate welfare of 5.5 percent of real consumer income (column 4 in table 5.3), according to our model. The marginal impact of imposing uniform tariffs is 2.0 percent. The impact on output by sector is similar to that in the 25 percent maximum tariff scenario. 200) The combined effect of tariffying nontariff barriers and lowering tariff protection has a strong positive impact on the income of the poorest households, with the income of the poorest rural household type rising 20 percent and the income of the poorest urban household type rising 11 percent. All households gain, but the percentage increase in income declines monotonically with income, since the equal lump-sum transfers of the fiscal surplus represent a larger percentage of income for poorer households. 201) Given tariffication the marginal impact of lowering tariff protection has a revenue impact on government revenues. The adverse fiscal impact is greater under the 25 percent maximum tariff scenario (0.7 decline in revenue) than under the 15 percent uniform tariff (0.4 percent decline in revenue). The second option has less negative an effect on fiscal balances because low tariffs are raised to 15 percent, partly offsetting the revenue loss associated with lowering tariffs above 15 percent. Since the impact on the poor is primarily a function of the lump-sum transfers and the negative fiscal effect can be assumed to cause a lump-sum transfer from households to the government, the marginal impact on the poor of lowering tariff protection given prior tariffication is negative. The combined impact of tariffication plus lowering tariff barriers is positive for the poor, provided they receive their share of the fiscal surplus generated as transfers. Adopting Integrated Pricing Reforms 202) By evaluating a combination of policy scenarios, we determine the relative importance of the various reforms and the magnitude of the combined effects (tables 5.5 and 5.6). Our results should help inform the discussion of key policy reforms. 63 Table 5.5. Impact of Trade, Exchange Rate, and Energy Pricing Reforms (percentage change from initial equilibrium) Energ y pricing reform + initial Tariffication + Tariffication + Energy pricing tariffication + exchange rate situation exchange rate exchange rate Energy reform + unifica, ion + tariff reform Item (level unification + unification + zero pricing exchange rate 15% uniform values) uniform 15% tariffs tariffs reform unification tari0fs Zero tariffs (0) (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) Aggregate welfare change - 12.3 12.7 32.9 38.8 50.1 50.7 (percent of income) Fiscal effects (percent of GDP) Food subsidies - - - - - - - Foreign exchange subsidies -6.4 6.4 6.4 2.1 6.4 t.4 6.4 Petroleumsubsidies -18.1 0.8 -0.3 18.1 18.1 18.1 18.1 Import taxes 0.3 1.6 -0.3 0.1 0.1 .. 1 -0.3 Oil rent 15.7 -2.2 -0.6 -7.0 -9.2 -8.1 -6.6 Net effect - 6.6 5.1 13.3 15.3 1;.5 17.6 Average effective tariff rate 2.5 14.0 - 2.7 2.9 14.7 - (percent) Trade effects Real exchange rate n.a. -8.5 -3.5 -26.1 -35.5 -31.9 -26.1 Aggregate exports n.a. -17.2 -8.9 30.4 16.6 25.8 35.3 Factor incomes Wage rate n.a. 3.1 3.2 2.4 7.7 8.4 7.8 Return to capital n.a. -3.7 -1.3 -6.1 -7.1 -'.8 -3.7 Price of essential goods Primary food items n.a. 13.5 13.1 8.2 19.4 24.9 23.9 Food products n.a. 7.4 6.9 4.3 8.1 1 0.3 9.5 Sugar n.a. 40.9 41.9 -0.3 36.4 41.6 42.1 Pharmaceuticals n.a. 2.1 3.1 -4.0 -1.2 0.4 1.4 Change in household welfare Rural I n.a. 95.6 77.7 209.8 239.1 292.2 282.9 Rural 2 n.a. 60.8 50.5 139.0 157.2 193.3 188.7 Rural 3 n.a. 42.5 36.1 98.5 112.8 140.2 137.4 Rural 4 n.a. 38.1 32.9 90.0 102.4 128.1 126.2 Rural 5 n.a. 30.7 27.1 73.1 84.0 105.9 104.7 Rural 6 n.a. 24.0 21.9 58.7 67.8 86.3 85.8 Rural 7 n.a. 20.8 19.5 51.6 60.0 77.1 77.2 Rural 8 n.a. 19.6 18.7 49.5 56.8 7:3.6 74.2 Rural 9 n.a. 12.9 13.4 34.6 40.6 53.9 55.0 Rural 10 n.a. 2.8 5.2 11.9 15.6 21.6 23.2 Urban 1 n.a. 44.3 37.3 102.6 116.3 143.1 139.5 Urban 2 n.a. 28.9 25.4 70.3 79.8 99.4 97.9 Urban 3 n.a. 22.4 20.3 55.1 63.5 80.0 79.2 Urban 4 n.a. 18.9 17.7 47.5 54.9 69.8 69.6 Urban 5 n.a. 16.3 15.8 41.8 48.4 62.0 62.2 Urban 6 n.a. 14.4 14.3 37.8 43.9 56.5 56.9 Urban 7 n.a. 12.0 12.5 32.1 37.7 49 2 49.9 Urban 8 n.a. 8.8 10.0 25.1 29.9 39 6 40.7 Urban 9 n.a. 5.7 7.5 18.4 22.6 30 3 31.5 Urban 10 n.a. 2.3 5.0 10.5 13.9 19<4 21.1 n.a. Not applicable Source: Authors' estimates 64 0 ~~~~~~~~~~ ~ ~ ~ ~~~~ 0~~~~~ zN AC) '~ g 000C C. C) 0 PI ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ C 0~ - 00 90 -~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~r 5 PE El~~ E. -o M ND CD~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~C CD ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ C ~ -C CD CD~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~C ft . . .......... ........ .-...... .... .................. ........... .... ... . ...... ............. . ..... . .... ... .... 7" 6 i3~~~~~~~~~~~~~ to to ON ON t O t - C O to to ON t N O L t o - ON t O O C to L 0 NO - O to - t - t O6O 6 6 61 L. 6 L, i~~~~~~~~~~~~ 61 ;P, j, ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ C - - - - to NO - to - to to to LA - to to to NJ to to NO 00 - DO NO~~~~~~~ ON NO to CN NO N C O ON 0 o ON N - N to N ~.000 00 ~-~ ON N '0A N~ to N to 0 NO N to N to ON.ON .. N O O N.. ..... . .. . ...to .. .. ON ... ........ 0 . .. C..... . - .............. ..ON.N....O .. ....... .. ........... t o o. ON ..........-.. to....N . ON .. ..0 .... ..... ON. ....0 0. Ul 6~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~f N N-NJ to ON N - - - - N o N - to to N N N N N N ON N NZft 00 NNN tC0000 N ON A O 1 D O to o to t…00ON N OC A N N.,N NO 00 C ON - ON NO LA ON ON ON to - 00 00 0 LA NO ON - to LA to ON LA C ON NO 0 NO to - - ON to - NO LA ON ON ON2 ----N - -- - ........... -....o o t 0 - t o N N....to... . N.....O .... to ON 0 - NO ON ON LAO ON~~~~~~~~C '0C C ON C ON to too o 0 -0 LA NO - ON NO NO - ON NO 0 to to LA to C ON~~~~~91 91 1 71 - ON 0 t -000 L CO to J 0 NO 0 0000 to to 0 0 0 Nto LA O ON NO ON 0 ~ LA NOON o ON ON LA ON f ON NJ CD - to - N N O N Oto00toto O N O Nto 000000 - to N N 00 - - N - to - to~~~tg 6 to ON to ON to to - NO C - - NO LA 0 to LA to ON 00 to NO LA to ON ON to to ON LA NO - LA C 0 0 NO 00 to to NO to LA to '0~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~, 6, 6 ON LA CD CON ON LA ON 0000 to 000 to NO 00 00 ON to O C to to to ON to LA C LA NJ LA ON ON - NO ON NO 9o - ----- ------- . ... - ------- --- - -------- -- --- . ....... ........ .... . .... . ... N N to N N N N N N N N NO to - to N N N N N N N NO N N to N N NDNN..NO ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~N'~~N0 - ON to LA C C NO C C LA ON NO ON N LA ON - LA NO ON ON - NO ON ON LA o to to totototot C LA to to ON t ON NO ON 00 ON LA ON tOO NO NO - NO to ON NOON o to LA 0 to ON Do to ON ON LA ON 0 N-A NO -000 to LA ON -0-0 -0 0 00 NO~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~ 9 N N N N * * N N * N N N N N N N N k N k * * N N NN7N Nr N LA to LA A ON ON L ON to ONNO ON ON -A LA LA A ON to O LA LA ON to ON LA N ON CD f LA ON ONONLA to -~~~~~~~~~~~~~~61Z~t NO t 00 N O ON N L - ON 0 to CD NO LA 00000000 ON 0to90 NO 9 90900 ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~0 '00000 to. ~ ~ ~~~~~ ~~ ON9 Reforming Petroleum Prices 203) Domestic petroleum prices in Iran are only about 10 percent of world prices. Eliminating the subsidy to domestic consumption of petroleum products potentially has strong links with trade and exchange rate reform. In particular, the elimination of subsidies to petroleum product consLumption will increase the relative costs of energy intensive industries. This could change the pattern of 2omparative advantage, inducing Iran to export more crude oil and more of products that do not use energy intensively, and import more of the products that use energy intensively. It will also induce Iran to use energy more efficiently, reflecting the value of oil and petroleum products on world markets. Moreover, the additional exports of oil would be expected to induce a real appreciation of the Rial that in turn will adversely impact on non-traditional exports and put further pressure on import competing indLIstries. 204) The results of Table 5.5 are consistent with theory. The elimination of the petroleum subsidies results in a strong increase in exports of crude oil of 76 percent. The additional crude oil exports earn additional foreign exchange so that the real exchange rate appreciates by 26 percent in ordetr to restore equilibrium in the balance of trade. Aggregate exports and imports increase by 30 percent. 'I'hus, import competing sectors contract and non-traditional exports contract by more than 50 percent, while oil exports expand. This phenomenon is sometimes referred to as "Dutch disease." 205) This scenario results in an enormous increase in welfare of 33 percent of consumption (column 3 in table 5.5). The results are explained by the fact that oil moves to where it is valued more highly (world markets) and the economy uses petroleum products more efficiently. If the fiscal surplus fronm eliminating the petroleum product subsidies is transferred back to households in equal amounts, the income of the poorest urban household type doubles, while that of the poorest rural household type rises by more than 200 percent. Combining Trade and Exchange Rate Reform 206) In these scenarios we combine the effects of tariffying nontariff barriers, unifying the exchange rate for imports and exports and lowering tariffs. We consider two tariff policies: a uniform tariff of 15 percent and zero tariffs. Under the first policy, the welfare gain is 12.3 percent of consumption; under the second policy, the gain is 12.7 percent. The poor gain enormously from these combined policies, but they benefit slightly more under the 15 percent uniform tariff, because there is less fiscal surplus to distribute to the poor if tariffs are eliminated. The impact on production is dominated by the sectors that benefit from eliminating the foreign exchange subsidies. Combining Energy and Exchange Rate Reform 207) Combining exchange rate reform with energy reform increases the aggregate welfare gain to 39 percent of benchmark consumption (column 4 in table 5.5). Since both energy and exchange rate reform increase government revenues, there is an enormous potential increase in welfare to the poor if the fiscal surplus is distributed to households as a lump sum. The poorest urban household type gains 116 percent, and the poorest rural household group gains 239 percent. All households gain, but the percentage gains decrease with the household's income level. Combining Trade, Energy, and Exchange Rate Reform 208) We estimate the gains from combining all the key policy reforms based on two different policy options: a uniform 15 percent tariff (column 5 in table 5.5) and free trade (colunm 6 in table 5.5). Our 66 estimates suggest that the Iranian economy would enjoy an enormous gain of more than 50 percent of the value of consumption as a result of the combined reforms. Aggregate gains under both the zero tariff option and the uniform 15 percent tariff are estimated at more than 50 percent of consumption. The poor gain slightly more from the uniform tariff of 15 percent because the fiscal surplus is larger when tariffs are not eliminated. 67 ANNEX 5A. DATA AND MODEL CONSTRUCTION To calibrate our model, we constructed a database that represents a benchmark equilibrium. We used four main data sources to construct the database: (1) an 10 table for Iran for 1994-95; (2) a household expenditure survey of Iran from 1994-95; (3) policy data, including tariffs, subsidies to imports and energy products, and tariff equivalence of nontariff barriers from various Iranian ministries and agencies, including the Central Bank, the Ministry of Industry, the Ministry of Commerce, and the Customs Department; and (4) estimates of Iranian elasticities (where available). We combined the data into a social accounting matrix, which constitutes the basis for our modeling effort. The I0 table provides data on the costs of intermediate inputs and value-added (labor and capital) in 43 production sectors, and it distinguishes household demand, government demand, investment demand, export demand, and import supply by sector. Household demand is divided into two categories: urban household demand and rural household demand. To further disaggregate households. we use the household expenditure survey to decompose both rural and urban households into 10 hous&,hold types, grouped according to income. That is, all Iranian households are grouped into one of 20 household types, depending on their income level and whether they live in a rural or an urban area. Unfortunately, the 10 table and the household expenditure survey are not consistent with respect to total rural and total urban household demand by sector. We therefore use share data from the household expenditure survey to decompose the data on rural and urban household demand. For each sector and for both rural and urban households, we calculate each of the 10 household types' share in total household demand by sector in the household expenditure survey and then apply those shares in the lT table. We then have a table with the 20 households' expenditures on output from the 43 production sectors. Neither the 10 table nor the household expenditure survey provides data on the incorne pattern by household type, leaving us with no information on the distribution of income across factors of production or on the sector from which the income comes. We therefore make the strong assumption that all households have identical income patterns. The 10 table also contains little information on the policies we want to analyze; the data that it does contain-collected import tariff revenues-do not represent current policies. We have therefcre relied on Iranian ministries for our data on policy parameters for tariffs and nontariff barriers to imports, foreign exchange subsidies, and subsidies to domestic petroleum consumption. The 10 table reports the costs of imports to users, so in constructing the social accounting matrix, we incorporate the data on barriers to imports by deducting the costs of the barriers to arrive at the border costs of the imports. In the case of foreign exchange subsidies, we derive the border costs of the imports by adding the value of the foreign exchange subsidy to the user costs of imports to arrive at the border costs. The data on subsidies to domestic petroleum consumption were derived on the basis of table S.Al, which shows the difference between the domestic and international prices of four petroleum products. 68 Table 5A1. Estimated Domestic and International Prices for Petroleum Products, 1999/2000 Domestic price Intemational pricea Ratio Subsidy rate Product (rials/liter) (rials/liter) (percent) (percent) Gasoline 350.0 1329.2 26.3 73.7 Kerosene 100.0 1254.3 8.0 92.0 Gas oil 100.0 1136.9 8.8 91.2 Fuel oil 50.0 880.6 5.7 94.3 a International prices are converted to rials at the market exchange rate on the Tehran Stock Exchange of 8,150 rials per dollar. Source: Ministry of Oil and authors' calculations. The price of gasoline in Iran was 26 percent of the international price, and the domestic price of kerosene, gas oil, and fuel oil were less than 10 percent of the international price. Given that international prices are exogenous to the Iranian economy, these prices therefore imply an implicit subsidy of almost 75 percent on gasoline and more than 90 percent for the other three petroleum products. Since petroleum subsidies apply to domestic consumption, they effectively apply to both imports and domestic production. In the case of imports, we add the subsidy to the user costs of imports to obtain the border costs of the petroleum imports. In the case of domestic production, we add the subsidy to the costs of production. Our database also includes a set of elasticities. Many sources were used for the elasticities. We employed the study of Ahangarani (1999) who estimated a system of demand functions for Iran. We also employed the study by Hope and Singh (1995) for energy elasticities. These studies suggest that the price elasticities of demand for different energy goods are between -0.2 and -1. We employed -0.4. In a CES function with a small energy cost share this implies an elasticity of substitution of 0.4. These studies suggest income and price elasticities of household goods of about 1 and -1, respectively. This corresponds to a Cobb-Douglas utility function. Some essential household goods are reported to have price elasticities less than unity. We choose -0.4 for these goods. In most economies, the capital-value share in total value-added is constant in the long run, which is consistent with a Cobb-Douglas production function for total value added. Most studies suggest low substitutability between most intermediate inputs in different product categories, corresponding to the Leontief production function for the aggregate of intermediate goods (see, for example, de Melo and Tarr, 1992). Finally, most studies suggest energy demand elasticities in production between -0.2 and -0.7 - we chose an average value of -0.5. In the remaining cases, we use estimates employed in sirnilar analyses, such as de Melo and Tarr (1992); Harrison, Rutherford, and Tarr (1993); and Rutherford, Rutstrom, and Tarr (1994). In particular, we choose a value of three for the elasticity of substitution between domestic and foreign varities in demand. For energy goods, which are relatively homogeneous, we choose a value of six. Figures 5.1 and 5.2 show the nesting structure of the production functions and the utility functions along with the assumed elasticities of substitution. 69 ANNEX 5B: COMPENSATING THE POOR FOR THE REMOVAL OF PRICE SUBSIDIES ON THE CONSUMPTION OF ESSENTIAL GOODS In absolute terms, the rich gain far more than the poor from subsidies that hold down th, prices of essential goods, such as flour, pharmaceuticals, electricity and other fuels. These items make up a higher share of total expenditure for the poor than for the rich, but this effect is dominated by the mujch greater absolute expenditures of the rich, relative to the poor. According to the estimates in World Bank (1999, Tables 14A and 14B), the per capita benefits of fuel subsidies to members of the richest urban quintile were 6.7 times the per capita benefits to those in the poorest urban quintile. For the rural quintiles the corresponding ratio was 5.5. To avoid wasteful over-consumption of subsidized goods, and to raise the share of the poor in total benefits, we recommend that price subsidies be removed and that compensation be provided in the form of equal lump sum amounts payable to all households.29 Iran already has a mechanism for dctstributing ration coupons for edible oils, sugar and cheese. Every holder of an ID card can go to a bank regardless of whether or not they have an account there) and collect ration coupons. The bank stamps the 11D card to show that the coupons have been handed out. The ID card is a booklet that contains a recent photo of the holder and space to allow the bank to stamp it at regular intervals over a two year period. Th, coupons can be used to buy subsidized goods at controlled retail prices from grocery stores. The stores must match coupons collected from customers with price controlled goods delivered by government agencies, or pay the difference to the government. This system could easily be amended to distribute cash instead of coupons. If substantial amounts of cash were distributed through the existing coupon system, it would be subject to additional stresses that do not apply when only small amounts of low quality goods are involved. There are already incentives to retain ID cards for those who have died or emigrated. and these abuses would increase as the benefits paid to card holders increased. Cards can also be lost or stolen. Because of the photos, it is hard to use someone else's card unless a bank official collaborates in the fraud, but some bank officials may do this, and if severe penalties were enforced they might bc inflicted on those who had made honest mistakes. Further study of ways to minimize the abuses that cash transfers might create would clearly be necessary. However, admninistrative problems are not unique to cash transfers and would confront any welfare system. Some critics of uniform cash transfers argue that it is wrong to help the rich as wvell as the poor, and that cash subsidies should therefore be targeted to the poor and denied to the rich. Against this, we would make three points. First, targeting subsidies is administratively costly and has the major disadvantage that it would generate high marginal rates of tax on incomes just above the poverty line defining eligibility for the full handouts. These high marginal tax rates would tend to create a poverty trap by reducing the incentives for the poor to help themselves. (A negative income tax system, however, could in principle avoid the problem of high marginal rates of taxation.) Second, as the above estimates from World Bank (1999) show, the rich benefit from the existing price subsidies, and in fact they benefit far more than the poor in absolute terms, whereas by definition everyone would benefit equally, in absolute terms, from a uniform cash payment. Third, to compensate the poor, the cash transfers need only be set equal to the amount that they gain from price subsidies, which is far less than the average gain to all citizens from these subsidies. Importantly, as Iran obtains experience with administering a cash 29 Since children eat less than adults. and since the per person cost of fuel is less for large families than for small one:., there is a case for smaller payments per person in large families than in small ones. 70 distribution system it could be progressively targeted to the poor, including possibly the introduction of a negative income tax system. The estimates in World Bank (1999) imply that the per capita gains from fuel subsidies were Rls 165,000 and Rls 227,000 for the poorest quintiles in rural and urban areas, respectively. In contrast, the average gains were Rls 472,000 and Rls 585,000 respectively. A flat payment of Rls 227,000 to everyone would therefore have compensated the members of the poorest urban quintile and more than compensated the members of the poorest rural quintile. This is about $28 per person per year, at the current open market exchange rate. The actual cash handout per person that would now be needed to just compensate members of the poorest quintile for the removal of all price subsidies would be higher than $28 per year because world fuel prices have risen since the above estimates were calculated, and because the above estimates apply only to fuel subsidies, and exclude basic foods.30 Setting relatively low cash handouts that would only compensate the poor for the removal of price subsidies would have two advantages. It would minimize the incentives for the rich to go to the trouble of collecting their entitlements, and it would allow the government to reduce other taxes, relatively to what they would otherwise have been. However, if further study suggested that it would be feasible to administer a system of flat rate cash subsidies at the higher rate corresponding to the average benefits to all households from existing price subsidies, or even to the much higher per capita cost to the government of providing all existing price subsidies, it would be possible to reduce poverty substantially, rather than merely compensate the poor for the removal of the existing price subsidies. The important point is the flat rate cash subsidies needed merely to compensate the poor for the removal of price subsidies are sufficiently low that we doubt that they would result in excessive abuses of the ID card system. For the above reasons, we are confident in recommending that all price subsidies be removed and replaced by flat rate cash transfers. In addition, we think that further study may well confirm the administrative feasibility of setting cash subsidies at a rate that would be high enough to substantially alleviate poverty, rather than merely compensate the poor for the removal of price subsidies. 30 Compensation for the removal of price subsidies for pharmaceuticals should be provided through the health insurance system, because the compensation needed by individuals with certain major illnesses would be far in excess of the compensation needed on average. 71 6. SEQUENCING REFORMS 209) The Third Five Year Development Plan incorporates an ambitious program of reforms and in this report we have suggested still further reforms. To avoid discouraging potential private investors by creating unnecessary uncertainty, the government will need to commit itself to a credible ind detailed timetable for these reforms. An essential element of any credible plan is that the government must anticipate the possible effects of reforms on unemployment and the poorest groups in society and implement policies to offset potentially adverse effects. The proposed reforms of the exzhange rate system and of fuel subsidies will produce large fiscal gains to the government budget, which will be reinforced by proposed reforms to direct and indirect taxation. They should therefore provide the government with ample revenue to finance policies needed to offset possible adverse effects on unemployment and the poor. 210) Since the methods currently used to alleviate poverty are not well targeted, it shoulcl be possible to design more effective methods at a modest budgetary cost. Moreover, since the reforms will remove barriers to non-oil exports-industries that are intensive users of unskilled and semi-skilled labor-the aggregate effect of the reforms may well be to boost demand for these types of labor. However, the whole purpose of reforming trade policy and reducing input subsidies is to change relative prices and cause resources to move from activities in which their marginal social productivity is relatively low :o activities in which it is higher. This will inevitably lead to job creation and expansion in some sectors and to job losses and the closure of firms in others. 211) The sectors likely to be adversely affected by the reform program are those that have relatively high barriers to imports and those that are intensive users of subsidized oil products. The industries that receive the greatest protection from imports are those that produce finished manufactures, particularly garments and vehicles. Following reform, therefore, the transport sector may shrink, but it will inevitably survive. The most important users of oil products are the transport, petrochemicals, and steel, cement, and brick-making industries. Given Iran's abundant fuel supplies, even without subsidies or protection from imports, these industries will almost certainly be viable, provided that they are efficiently operated. There is no reason why Iran should not be internationally competitive in all these industries follow.ng reform. However, to make Iranian firms competitive at international prices in these sectors as well as in vehicle production, it may be necessary to privatize them and allow the new owners to restructure therr. 212) The govemment will need to ensure that the regulatory and legal environment becomes more conducive to private enterprise. This will be important both for ensuring the viability of privatized enterprises and for ensuring that entrepreneurs who wish to set up wholly new private enterpriL es are able to do so. In turn, the successful development of a vigorous private sector is very important fOr ensuring the long-term viability of the reforms. The reforms that are needed to achieve this objective are not merely the trade sector reforms dealt with in this report, though these are essential, but also: * the removal of barriers to trade and investment in services, * the introduction of competition policy to minimize barriers to all potential new firms, * the modernization of the systems of direct and indirect taxation. 213) One of the most important aspects of the liberalization of trade and investment in servizes will be financial deregulation, but other service sectors will also need to be deregulated if Iranian bus,:nesses are to be able to compete on equal terms with foreign competitors after the opening up of trade in goods. 72 Reforming the regulatory environment so that policies are in place that encourage the entry of new firms will be urgently needed both to ensure that new private entrants to markets that were formerly dominated by state enterprises are able to compete on equal terms. It has been shown that free entry is the most effective competition policy 31 to stop new private owners of formerly state owned monopolies from capturing all the benefits of privatization in the form of monopoly profits. Finally, an efficient tax system is an essential feature of an environment that is conducive to private enterprise. 214) The three policy areas listed above are largely outside the scope of this report. Although the tax system was mentioned in section 2.3, that section focused only on current differences in the tax treatment of domestic and traded goods. Similarly, although financial reforms were mentioned in section 4.3 that section focused only on trade finance. There is therefore a need for other broader studies to explore in detail the reforms that are needed in the areas of trade and investment in services, competition policy and taxation. Several studies of tax reform have already been undertaken, however there is a need for further studies of the scope for competition policy and the liberalization of trade and investment in services. 215) The timetable suggested in table 6.1-which incorporates and extends the plans of several government ministers who support economic reform-proposes unifying the exchange rates and converting nontariff barriers into their tariff equivalents by March 2002. The conversion of nontariff barriers to tariffs will require an increase in the commercial benefit tax on the most heavily protected items. However, merely to keep effective import tax rates unchanged in real terms when exchange rates are unified will require very large reductions in the legal rates. These reductions will be needed because import duties are calculated by multiplying the legal duty rates by the value of imports at the official exchange rate. If the official exchange rate (at which imports are valued for the calculation of import duties) is raised from 1,750 to about 8,175 rials per dollar (that is, by a factor of 4.67) all legal import tax rates would have to be divided by 4.67 merely to leave the amount of tax payable in rials unchanged. 216) If the Ministry of Industry's estimates of the tariff equivalents of existing nontariff barriers are accurate, the total import taxes on the items under the responsibility of the Ministry of Industry would be 37 percent and the maximum import tax rate would be 100 percent. The unweighted economywide average total import tax for all items would be about 30 percent. 217) To improve the efficiency of resource allocation and encourage growth and poverty reduction (as well as gain entry into the WTO), it will be necessary to reduce the average level of import taxes after tariffication, narrow the dispersion between these taxes, and reduce fuel subsidies. Under the proposals summarized in table 6.1, fuel subsidies would be gradually eliminated over a four-year period beginning in March 2001. The average levels of import taxes would be progressively reduced between March 2002 and March 2005, by which time there would be a uniform import tax of 15 percent. 218) Deciding which import taxes will be reduced when is likely to involve a great deal of lobbying and uncertainty. To minimize these problems and simplify the process as much as possible, the government could announce that beginning in March 2003 (when import taxes would be below the tariff equivalents of existing nontariff barriers), only a few import tax bands will exist. Setting a small number of tariff bands would have no particular economic benefit or cost. Setting a date after which there could no be no further lobbying for tariff reductions could have a political benefit, however. 219) To see the advantages of reducing the number of bands, to say, four, suppose that only 10 percent of items are placed in the highest band and that the remaining items are equally distributed among the 31 See Hoekman, Kee and Olarreaga (2001). 73 other three bands. Setting import tax bands for March 2003 at 3 percent, 20 percent, 40 percent. and 60 percent would satisfy the condition that the average import tax be 25 percent and the rnaximum 60 percent.32 Setting bands for March 2004 at 10 percent, 18 percent, 25 percent, and 40 percent would satisfy the condition that the average import tax be 20 percent, with a maximum of 40 percent.33 All import taxes would be unified at 15 percent by March 2005. 220) There is nothing especially important about the particular choice of bands suggested above- many others might be just as good. The advantage of picking any one of the many possible sensible choices is that it would reduce the scope for lobbying to the question of which band any particular item would be placed in. The economics ministries would make a preliminary assignment of iterns to the four bands; lobbying groups could get particular items assigned to higher bands only by having other items assigned to lower ones. Once the bands had been chosen, the future path of all tariifs would be determined. After all tariffs had been unified, there would be a strong case for passing an act of Parliament to replace the commercial benefit tax and customs duty with a single tariff. 320.3 x 3% + 0.3 x 20% + 0.3 x 40% + 0.1 x 60% =24.9%. 30.3 x10% + 0.3 x 18% + 0.3 x 25% + 0.1 x 40% = 19.9%. 74 APPENDIX: TRADE DATA FOR IRAN Table Al. Iranian Exports by Major Partner, 1989-99 Partner 1989 1995 1997 1999 Export Value in $ million World 11609.0 18360.0 18381.0 19726.0 United Arab 0.0 285.3 285.6 598.7 Emirates Germany 657.8 391.0 391.5 423.0 Turkey 891.8 90.1 90.2 183.4 Italy 1420.3 275.2 275.5 181.4 India 150.2 95.0 95.1 128.6 Turkmenistan .. 146.0 146.2 122.3 Azerbaijan .. 193.5 193.7 119.2 Iraq .. .. .. 98.5 Taiwan, China .. 66.5 66.6 97.2 Canada 112.5 54.8 54.9 95.6 China 63.8 62.1 62.1 77.3 Russia .. 45.5 45.5 62.0 Korea .. 94.8 94.9 60.9 Netherlands 1302.8 66.6 66.6 59.6 Japan 2102.6 104.2 104.3 57.1 Top 15 partners 6701.8 1970.5 1972.7 2364.8 Rest of the World 4907.2 16389.5 16408.3 17361.2 As % of Total Exports World 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 United Arab 0.0 1.6 1.6 3.0 Emirates Germany 5.7 2.1 2.1 2.1 Turkey 7.7 0.5 0.5 0.9 Italy 12.2 1.5 1.5 0.9 India 1.3 0.5 0.5 0.7 Turkmenistan .. 0.8 0.8 0.6 Azerbaijan .. 1.1 1.1 0.6 Iraq .. .. .. 0.5 Taiwan, China .. 0.4 0.4 0.5 Canada 1.0 0.3 0.3 0.5 China 0.5 0.3 0.3 0.4 Russia .. 0.2 0.2 0.3 Korea .. 0.5 0.5 0.3 Netherlands 11.2 0.4 0.4 0.3 Japan 18.1 0.6 0.6 0.3 Top 15 partners 57.7 10.7 10.7 12.0 Rest of the World 42.3 89.3 89.3 88.0 Source: UN COMTRADE Statistics. 75 Table A2. Iranian Imports by Major Partner, 1989-99 Partner 1989 1995 1997 1999 Import Value in $ million World 10697.0 13882.0 14180.7 12621.8 Germany 2043.7 1814.9 1853.9 1382.2 Italy 714.4 778.3 795.1 901.5 United Arab Emirates .. 550.3 562.1 768.6 South Africa .. 121.6 124.2 721.1 France 251.8 661.0 675.2 685.4 Brazil 361.4 287.4 293.6 681.3 China 162.5 386.2 394.6 613.2 Japan 1467.6 863.1 881.7 590.2 Russia .. 689.5 704.3 531.5 Canada 180.9 603.5 616.4 530.9 United Kingdom 701.5 667.1 681.4 439.1 Spain 143.6 257.5 263.0 341.3 Switzerland 310.5 520.2 531.4 336.0 Austria 193.5 259.0 264.6 303.8 Australia 337.8 510.7 521.7 298.4 Top 15 partners 6869.3 8970.1 9163.2 9124.5 Rest of the World 3827.7 4911.9 5017.6 3497.3 As % of Total Imports World 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 Germany 19.1 13.1 13.1 11.0 Italy 6.7 5.6 5.6 7.1 United Arab Emirates .. 4.0 4.0 6.1 South Africa .. 0.9 0.9 5.7 France 2.4 4.8 4.8 5.4 Brazil 3.4 2.1 2.1 5.4 China 1.5 2.8 2.8 4.9 Japan 13.7 6.2 6.2 4.7 Russia .. 5.0 5.0 4.2 Canada 1.7 4.3 4.3 4.2 United Kingdom 6.6 4.8 4.8 3.5 Spain 1.3 1.9 1.9 2.7 Switzerland 2.9 3.7 3.7 2.7 Austria 1.8 1.9 1.9 2.4 Australia 3.2 3.7 3.7 2.4 Top 15 partners 64.2 64.6 64.6 72.3 Rest of the World 35.8 35.4 35.4 27.7 Source: UN COMTRADE Statistics. 76 Table A3. Iranian Export Structure and Major Products, 1989-99 Export As % of Value in all $ million exports _______________________ ~~~~~~~~(%) Product (SITC Rev. 2) 1989 1995 1997 1999 1989 1995 1997 1999 All goods (0 to 9) 11609.0 18360.0 18381.0 19726.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 Food and live animals (0) 320.0 637.9 638.7 808.0 2.8 3.5 3.5 4.1 Beverages and tobacca (1) 0.1 7.4 7.4 7.8 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 Crude materials, excl. fuels (2) 297.8 240.5 240.7 186.2 2.6 1.3 1.3 0.9 Fuels (3) 10246.1 15712.3 15730.3 16842.5 88.3 85.6 85.6 85.4 Animal and vegetable oil (4) 0.0 12.9 12.9 5.1 0.0 0.1 0.1 0.0 Chemical products (5) 6.0 348.3 348.7 244.0 0.1 1.9 1.9 1.2 Basic manufacturing (6) 649.1 1112.2 1113.5 1254.2 5.6 6.1 6.1 6.4 Machinery and transport equipment 65.5 53.4 53.5 87.8 0.6 0.3 0.3 0.4 (7) Misc. manufacturing goods (8) 17.4 200.7 200.9 193.0 0.1 1.1 1.1 1.0 Goods not classified by kind (9) 7.2 34.4 34.5 97.4 0.1 0.2 0.2 0.5 Agriculture (0+1+2+4-27-28) 617.8 836.2 837.2 945.6 5.3 4.6 4.6 4.8 Manufacturing (5+6+7+8-68) 737.9 1667.0 1668.9 1665.6 6.4 9.1 9.1 8.4 All non-oil products (0 to 9 -3) 1362.9 2647.7 2650.7 2883.5 11.7 14.4 14.4 14.6 Memo Items: Non-oil Major products cereal preparation etc. (048) 0.0 110.1 110.3 70.6 0.0 0.6 0.6 0.4 Fruits fresh and dried (057, ex nuts) 106.1 81.2 81.3 149.2 0.9 0.4 0.4 0.8 Nuts fresh and dried (0577) 143.4 207.6 207.9 333.0 1.2 1.1 1.1 1.7 Spices (075) 13.9 23.4 23.5 47.8 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.2 Hides and skins, excl. furs (211) 116.0 87.3 87.4 46.2 1.0 0.5 0.5 0.2 Organic chemicals (51) 2.1 143.7 143.8 98.6 0.0 0.8 0.8 0.5 carpets (659) 605.1 694.1 694.9 733.3 5.2 3.8 3.8 3.7 Iron and steel in primary forms (672) 0.0 145.6 145.7 161.4 0.0 0.8 0.8 0.8 Copper (682) 28.9 41.1 41.2 84.3 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.4 Clothing and accessories (84) 0.6 55.6 55.6 66.5 0.0 0.3 0.3 0.3 Above top 10 export products 1016.1 1589.8 1591.6 1790.9 8.8 8.7 8.7 9.1 Source: UN COMTRADE Statistics. 77 Table A4. Iranian Import Structure and Major Products, 1989-99 Import As % of Value in all $ million imports Product (SITC Rev. 2) 1989 1995 1997 1999 1989 1995 1997 1999 All goods (0 to 9) 10697.0 13882.0 14180.7 12621.8 100.0 10( 0 100.0 100.0 Food and live animals (0) 2254.8 2453.7 2506.5 1952.2 21.1 17 7 17.7 15.5 Beverages and tobacca (1) 48.3 7.7 7.9 5.7 0.5 0 1 0.1 0.0 Crude materials, excl. fuels (2) 292.5 617.2 630.4 639.5 2.7 4 4 4.4 5.1 Fuels (3) 399.0 259.1 264.7 214.4 3.7 ]. 9 1.9 1.7 Animal and vegetable oil (4) 267.0 436.2 445.6 523.8 2.5 3 1 3.1 4.1 Chemical products (5) 1636.9 1819.4 1858.5 1871.3 15.3 13 1 13.1 14.8 Basic manufacturing (6) 1883.1 2671.8 2729.3 2219.1 17.6 19 2 19.2 17.6 Machinery and transport equipment (7) 3406.2 4933.5 5039.7 4835.0 31.8 3'i 5 35.5 38.3 Misc. manufacturing goods (8) 403.5 409.0 417.8 330.3 3.8 29 2.9 2.6 Goods not classified by kind (9) 105.8 274.4 280.3 30.6 1.0 2 0 2.0 0.2 Agriculture (0+1+2+4-27-28) 2862.5 3227.0 3296.5 2930.9 26.8 23 2 23.2 23.2 Manufacturing (5+6+7+8-68) 7329.7 9680.0 9888.3 9154.4 68.5 69 7 69.7 72.5 All non-oil products (0 to 9 -3) 10298.0 13622.9 13916.0 12407.3 96.3 98 1 98.1 98.3 Memo Items: Wheat unmilled (041) 557.9 1084.4 1107.8 801.3 5.2 , 8 7.8 6.3 Rice (042) 338.8 240.4 245.6 325.9 3.2 1 7 1.7 2.6 Sugar and honey (061) 194.5 396.8 405.3 280.8 1.8 29 2.9 2.2 Fixed vegetable oils (423) 234.1 389.8 398.2 486.4 2.2 2 8 2.8 3.9 Medicinal prarm products (541) 296.4 384.8 393.0 392.5 2.8 2 8 2.8 3.1 Iron and steel in forms or shape (672-679) 673.2 1225.6 1252.0 1138.3 6.3 8 8 8.8 9.0 Steam engine (712) 90.3 206.4 210.9 424.1 0.8 1 5 1.5 3.4 Machinery tools for industries (728) 100.3 174.8 178.6 281.6 0.9 1.3 1.3 2.2 Metal working machinery (737) 38.8 98.5 100.6 508.0 0.4 0 7 0.7 4.0 Motor vehicle parts and accessories (784) 318.6 701.2 716.3 596.7 3.0 5 1 5.1 4.7 Above top 10 import products 2842.8 4902.8 5008.3 5235.5 26.6 35i3 35.3 41.5 Source: UN COMTRADE Statistics. 78 REFERENCES Ahangarani, Rouyan Mashayekh. 1999. "An Almost Ideal Demand System for Iran." IRDP Working Paper. Barzel, Yoram. 1974. "A Theory of Rationing by Waiting." The Journal of Law and Economics 17:73- 95. Bhagwati, J.N. 1971. "The generalized theory of distortions and welfare," in: J. Bhagwati, R.W. Jones, R.A. Mundell and J. Vanek, eds., Trade, balance of payments and growth: Papers in international economics in honor of Charlers P. Kindleberger (North-Holland, Amsterdam) 69-90. De Melo, J., and D.G. Tarr. 1990. "Welfare Costs of U.S. Quotas in Textiles, Steel, and Autos." Review of Economics and Statistics 72 (3): 489-497. . 1992. A General Equilibrium Analysis of U.S. Foreign Trade Policy. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press. . 1993. "Industrial Policy in the Presence of Wage Distortions: The Case of the U.S. Auto and Steel Industries." International Economic Review 34 (4): 833-851. Dollar, David. 1992. "Outward-Oriented Developing Economies Really Do Grow More Rapidly: Evidence from 95 LDCs, 1976-1985." Economic Development and Cultural Change 40 (3): 523- 544. Edwards, Sebastian. 1992. "Trade Orientation, Distortions and Growth in Developing Countries." Journal of Development Economics 39 (1): 31-57. . 1993. "Openness, Trade Liberalization, and Growth in Developing Countries." Journal of Economic Literature 31(3): 1358-93. . 1998. "Openness, Productivity and Growth: What Do We Really Know?" Economic Journal 108 (March): 383-98. Fitzgerald B., and T. Monson. 1989. "Preferential Credit and Insurance As Means to Promote Exports." World Bank Research Observer 4 (1). Harrison, Ann. 1996. "Openness and Growth: A Time-Series, Cross-Section Analysis for Developing Countries." Journal of Development Economics 48 (2): 419-47. Harrison, G.W., T.F. Rutherford, and D.G. Tarr. 1993. "Trade Reform in the Partially Liberalized Economy of Turkey." World Bank Economic Review 7 (2): 191-217. - 1997a. "Economic Implications for Turkey of a Customs Union With the European Union." European Economic Review 41: 861-870. -. 1997b. "Quantifying the Uruguay Round." Economic Journal 107 (September): 1405-1430 Hoekman, B., H. L. Kee, and M. Olarreaga. 2001. "Markups, Entry Regulation and Trade: Does Country Size Matter?" The World Bank, Washington DC. mimeo. 79 Hope, Elinar, and Balbir Singh. 1995. "Energy Price Increases in Developing Countries: Case Studies of Colombia, Ghana, Indonesia, Malaysia, Turkey and Zimbabu e." Policy Research Working Paper 1442, The World Bank.IMF (International Monetary ]Fund). 2000. International Financial Statistics. CD-ROM. Washington, D.C. International Trade Center. 1997. The Financing of Exports: A Guide for Developing Countries and Transition Economies. Geneva. Michalopoulos, Constantine. 1999. "Trade Policy and Market Access Issues for Developing Countries: Implications for the Millennium Round." World Bank Working Paper No. 2214. Washington, D.C. Ministry of Commerce, Islamic Republic of Iran. 2000. Export-Import Regulations. Tehran. -. (1999). Islamic Republic of Iran: Your Partner in Trade. Tehran. Ministry of Economic and Financial Affairs, Islamic Republic of Iran. 1998a. "Ana[lysis of the Performance of the Chahbahar Free Trade Zone." July. Tehran. . 1998b. "Analysis of the Performance of the Kish Free Trade Zone." September. Tehran. 1998c. "Analysis of the Performance of the Qeshm Free Trade Zone." September. Tehran. Morkre. M., and D.G. Tarr. 1980. Effects of Restrictions on United States Imports: Five Case Studies and Theory. Washington, D.C.: Federal Trade Commission. . 1995. "Reforming Hungarian Agricultural Trade Policy: A Quantitative Evaluation." Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv 131(1): 106-131. Plan and Budget Organization, Islamic Republic of Iran. 2000. The Third Plan Law: Economic, Social, and Cultural Development of the Islamic Republic of Iran, 1379-1383 (2000/01-20004/20005). Tehran. Sachs, J. D., and A. Wamer. 1995. "Economic Reform and the Process of Global Integration." In W.C. Brainard and G.L. Perry, eds., Brookings Papers on Economic Activity. Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution. Tarr, D.G., and M. Morkre. 1984. Aggregate Costs to the United States of Tariffs and Quotas on Imports. Washington, D.C.: Federal Trade Commission. Tarr, D.G., T. Rutherford and E. Rutsrom. 1997. "Morocco's Free Trade Agreement with the EU: A Quantitative Assessment," Economic Modelling, 14( 9):237-269. April. Wilson, J.S. 2000a. Technical Barriers to Trade and Standards, Challenges and Opportunities for Developing Countries Presented by the World Bank. Submitted to the Technical Barriers to Trade Committee Meeting, World Trade Organization. 2000b. The Development Challenge in Trade: Sanitary and Phytosanitary Stanlards. Paper prepared for the WTO Sanitary and Phytosanitary Standards Committee. World Bank Development Research Group, Washington, D.C. 80 World Bank. 1993. The East Asian Miracle: Economic Growth and Public Policy. New York: Oxford University Press. . 1999. Economic Aspects of Increasing Energy Prices to Boarder Price Levels in the Islamic Republic of Iran. Report 198031RN. Washington, D.C.: World Bank. . 2000c. Global Economic Prospects and Developing Countries 2001. Chapter Three, Washington, D.C.: World Bank. 81 Annex: Computer Code for the Model $to-le Simple Static Constant Returrs to Scale Model Slibinclude cgi input elimesuo No "Eliminate energy subsidies?" Yes $libinclude cgi input exogoil No "Exogenous crude oil exports?' Yes Slibinclude cgi input fxsubs No "Remove foreign exchange subsidies?" Yes $libinclude cgi input fsub No "Subsidize domestic food consumption?" Yes $libinclude cgi input ntbs No "Tariff reform?" Tariff Uniform 25 Free 15 $libinclude cgi input nobrent VA 'NTB rent" Sain Read the data: Set the aggregation level: $set dataset full Read the set definit_on: $3nclude %dataset%.set alias (g,i,j); Declare model parameters in data file: parameter iod Input-output demand vad Value added fin Final demand imp Import itx Net taxes on import uhe Urban households expenditures rhe Rural households expenditures; * Read the data set: $include %dataset%.dat Declare additional sets and model parameters: set fd Fonal demands - symbols / uhc Urban household consumption rhc Rural household consumption gov Government consumption inv Gross fixed capital accumulation stc Change in stocks exp Export set Households: hh All households /rCl*rlO,uOlIulO/, rh(hh) Rural households /rCl*rlC/, rh6(hh) Rural households (6 richest) /rOf*rlC/, uh(hh) Urban households /uOl*ulO/, uh6(hh) Urban households (6 richest; /uO5*ulO/, high(i) High demand price elasticity Energy: nr(i( Sectors with natural resources /frr.,,lvs,ext/ cru(i) Crude oil /ext/ tsp(i) Transportation /ltr,ptr/ ene(i) Energy products / KER Kerosene FOI Fuel oil GNE Gasollne GIL Gas oil LQG Liquid gas ELE Electricity NGS Natural gas pet(i) Subsidized energy products / KER Kerosene FOI Fuel oil G?NE Gasoline GIL Gas oil / op(i) Crude oil and refined oil products oth(i) Non-oil sectors * Foreign exchange: oe(i) Imports at the official excharge rate /frm,sgr,foo.pha,mac/ ess(i) Essential food items /frm,sgr,foo,pha/; oth(i) yes; oth(nr) no; oth)ene) no; op(cru) yes; op(ene) = yes; high(i) = yes; high(ene) = no; high(ess) = no; display op,oth,high; scaler va Flag for NTB rent equal to value-added costs exo Flag for exogenous crude oil exports; $if %ntbrent% == "VA" va = 1; $if %ntbrent% == "Gain" va = 0; $if %exogoil% == 'Yes" exo = 1; $if %exogoil% == NNo' exo = 0; parameter cO(hh) Consumption demand cdO(i,hh) Consumption demand by good gO Total government demand gdO(i) Government demand iO Total investment demand idO(i) Investment demand net of taxes eO(i) Total export demand edO(i) Export demand net of taxes ii(i,j) Intermediate demand net of taxes ldO(i) Labor payments kdO(i) Capital payments sff Elas of sub between spec capital and other factors phi Specific factor value share dO(i) Supply to domestic markets ty(i) Production taxes mO(i) Imports gross of tariffs pmO(i) Reference price of imports pdO(i) Reference price of domestic goods qO(i) Imports net of tariffs tm(i) Import tariffs pi(i) Reference price of aO(i) Armington supply lsO Labor supply ksO Capital supply nsO Endowment of natural resources gsO Government capital endowment bopdef Balance of payment deficit govdef Government deficit incsh(hh) Household income share nohh(hh) Number of households (share in total number of households) nohh6(hh) Number of households excluding the 4 poorest rural and urban gamma Energy subsidies alpha Exchange rate subsidy fsub Flag for endogenous food subsidies arm Armington elasticities eta Elasticity of supply eta("ext") 0.5; eta("lvs") = 3; eta("frm") = 3; gamma(i) = C; fsub(i) = 0; arm(i) = 3; arm(pet) 6; nohh(rh) = 0.38/(0.5*card(hh)); nohh(uh) = 0.62/(0.5*card(hh)); nohh6(rh6) = 0.38/'(0.5(card(uh6)+card(rh6))); nohh6(uh6) = 0.62/(0.5*(card(uh6)+card(rh6))); * Calibrate the model parameters: * Final demands: * Urban households cO(uh) = sum(i,uhe(i,uh)); cdO(i,uh) = uhe(i,uh); * Rural households cO(rh) = sum(i,rhe(i,rh)); cdO(i,rh) = rhe(i,rh); * Expenditure and income share of each urban income group in total income incsh(hh) = cO(hh)/(sum(i,fin(i,"uhc")+fin(i,"rhc"))); display incsh; gO = sum(i,fin(i,"gov")); gdO(i) = fin(i,"gov"); idO(i) = fin(i,"inv")+fin(i,"stc"): eO(i) = fin(i,"exp"); edO(i) = fin(i,"exp"); * Intermediate demands and value added: ii)i,j) = iod(i,j); *.vad("cap",i) = vad()cap",i)+vad("ntx",i); 1dO(i) = vad("lab",i); kdO(i) = vad("cap",i); * Domestic supply and production taxes: dO(i) = sum(j,ii(j,i))+ldO(i)+kdO(i) + vad("ntx",i) - edO(i); ty(i) = vad("ntx",i)/(dO(i)+edO(i)); * Imports and Armington supply: mO(i) = imp(i); tm(i)$mO(i) = itx(i)/mO(i); pmO(i) = l+tm(i); pdO(i) = 1; aO(i) = mO(i)*pmnO(i4)+dO(1); qO(i) = mO(i); Incorporate NTBs and tariffs: scalar kvs Capital value share ntbc Costs of NTBs; parameter ntbO Benchmark NTB rates; table trd(*,*) Import trade distortions TM CBTO TD NTB TD+CBT1 CBT1 PRM4 0.8 0.7 0.1 9.2 10.1 10 L.NS 0.8 0.7 0.1 19.1 20.1 20 OAG 0.8 0.7 0.1 14.2 15.1 15 MN\G 1.6 1.1 0.5 13.7 15.5 15 EXT 0 0 0 C.0 0.0 0 SGR 0 0 0 0.0 0.0 0 FOO 0.5 0.4 0.1 29.5 30.1 30 PPP 3.1 2.4 0.7 6.4 9.7 9 CMT 2.1 1 1.1 19.6 22.1 21 BRK 9.3 8.2 1.1 11.7 22.1 21 GCM 3 2.3 0.7 18.2 21.7 21 GLS 7.8 6.5 1.3 21.8 31.3 30 lIMP 6.4 5.3 1.1 14.8 22.1 21 TXT 2.7 2.3 0.4 69.8 74.4 74 CLC 14.2 1i.1 3.1 89.1 93.1 90 LEA 4.2 3.6 0.6 67.6 74.6 74 PLC 1.7 1.3 0.4 23.3 25.4 25 PHA 0 0 0 0.0 0.0 0 KER 0.1 0.1 0 0.0 0.1 0.1 FOI 0.1 0.1 0 O.C 0.1 0.1 GNE 0.1 0.1 0 0.0 0.1 0.1 GIL 0.1 0.1 0 0.0 0.1 0.1 LQG 0.1 0.1 0 0.0 0.1 0.1 OCP 2 1.7 0.3 7.2 9.3 9 MET 3.5 3.1 0.4 16.3 20.4 20 CAL 3.5 3.1 0.4 16.3 20.4 20 MPS 5.9 4.9 1 4.8 11.0 10 MAC 2.7 2.1 0.6 7.7 10.6 10 RTV 4 2.8 1.2 16.5 21.2 20 MEQ 3.5 2.1 1.4 32.8 37.4 36 OIP 3.4 2.9 0.5 16.5 20.5 20; tm(z) = trd(i,"tm")/10C; ntbOC(i) = trd(i,"ntb")/lCO; pmO(i) = (1+tm(i))1(l+ntbO(i)); mO(i) = (aO(i)-dO(i))/pmO(i); qO(i) = mO(i); ntbc = sum(i, mO(i)*(l+tm(i))*ntbO(i)); * Capital value share: kvs = sum(i,kdO(i))/sum(i,kdO(i)+ldO(i)); Incorporate energy subsidies: parameter ratio Ratio of domestic to international prices excor Correction of exchange rates; excor = 4172/8150; ratio('gne') = excor*O.514; ratio("ker') = excor,O.156; ratio("gil") = excor'O.172; ratio("foi") = excor*O.111; gamma(pet) = ratio(pet)-l; display gamma; * Eliminate small import taxes on oil products: mO(pet) = mO(pet)+itx(pet); qO(pet) = mO(pet); tm(pet) = 0; pmO(pet) = l+gamma(pet); pdO(pet) = l+gamma(pet); * Domestic production: parameter delta Change in domestic production; delta(pet) = (aO(pet)-mO(pet)*(l+gammna(pet)))/(l+gamma(pet))-dO(pet); dO(pet) = dO(pet)+delta(pet); ii("ext',pet) = ii("ext",pet)+delta(pet); kdO(ext') = kdO("ext')+sum(pet,delta(pet)); dO("ext") = dO(ext")+sum(pet,delta(pet)); aO('ext") = aO("ext")+sum(pet,delta(pet)); ty(i) = vad('ntx¾,i)/(dO(i)+edO(i)); b Incorporate dual pricing of foreign exchange: parameter fxsh Share of imports imported at the official exchange rate; fxsh("frm") = 0.8; fxsh("sgr") = 1; fxsh(Ufoo") = 0.4; fxsh(-pha") = 1; fxsh("mac") = 0.75; * Ratio of market exchange rate to official exchange rate alpha(oe) = ((l-fxsh(oe))*8.2+fxsh(oe)*1.75)/8.2-1; qO(oe) = qO(oe)/(l+alpha(oe)); display alpha; * Elasticity of substitution in sectors with specific capital: phi(nr) = 0.5*kdO(nr)/(edO(nr)+dO(nr)); sff(nr) = phi(nr)*eta(nr)/(l-phi(nr)); Closure rules: Capital and labor supply: gsO = 0.5'kdO('ext'); nsO(nr) = 0.5*kdO(nr); IsO = sum(i,ldO(i))+(l-kvs)*ntbc$va; ksO = sum(i,kdO(i))-gsO-sum(nr,nsO(nr))+kvslntbc$va; Benchmark deficits: bopdef = sum(i, qO(i)-eO(i)); govdef =nsO("ext') + gsO + sum(i, dO(i)*ty(i) + edO(i)*ty(i) + qO(i) alpha(i) + mO(i)'tm(i) t mO(i)*gamma(i) +dO(i)*gamma(i) - gO; Statistics: parameter aggr Aggregate statistics govstat Government incomes and expenditures fxs Imports with foreign exchange subsidies vastat Value-added statistics, ecs Energy cost shares, tsh Trade shares hhexp Household expenditure shares, inc Income shares, policy Summary of policy instruments; aggr('inc') = sum(hh,cO(hh)); aggr(-gdp") = sum(i,kdO(i)+ldO(i)); aggr(-ty') = sum(i,(dO(i)+edO(i))*ty(i)); aggr('ty%') = 100aggr('ty')/aggr("gdp'); aggr('ensub") = sum(i,-(mO(i)+dO(i))*gamma(i)); aggr("ensub%') =lOO1aggr("ensub")/aggr('gdp'); aggr(Utm') = sum(i,mO(i)*tm(i)); aggr('tm%") = lOO*aggr(tm1)/aggr("gdp'); aggr('fx') = sum(i, -qO(i)*alpha(i)); aggr('fx%-) = lOO1 aggr('fx")/aggr('gdp'); aggr("ntb') = sum(i, mO(i)*(l+tm(i))*ntbO(i)); aggr('ntb%') = l00*aggr('ntb')/aggr(Ugdp'); aggr("kvs') = lOO*sum(i,kdO(i))/aggr("gdp'); aggr('imps') = lOOsum(i,mO(i))/aggr(Vgdp'); aggr('oilrentn) =1O00dO('ext')/aggr("gdp'); govstat('ensub') =sum(i,(mO(i)+dO(i))*gamma(i)); govstat('tm") = sum(i,mO(i)ltm(i)); govstat('fx*) =sum(i,qO(i)*alpha(i)); govstat('oilrent') = nsO('ext'); fxsh(pet)SmO(pet) = ; fxs(i,'fxsh') = lOO*fxsh(i); fxs(i,'impsh') = lOO*fxsh(i)'mO(i)/sum(j,mO(j)); fxs('total',"impsh') =lOO*sum(i,fxsh(i)'mO(i))/sum(i,mO(i)); vastat(i,'k%") = lO0*kdO(i)/sum(j,kdO(j)); vastat(i,"l%-) = 100*ldO(i)/sum(j,ldO(j)); vastat(i,'va%') = lOO1(ldO(i)+kdO(i))/sum(j,ldO(j)+kdO(j)); vastat(i,'kvs') = lO0*kdO(i)/(ldO(i)+kdO(i)); ecs(i) = lOO*sum(ene,ii(ene,i))/(edO(i)+dO(i)); tsh(i,'imp') = lOO*mO(i)/sum(j,mO(j)); tsh(i,'impsub') = l00*qO(i)/sum(j,qO(j)); tsh(i,'exp') = l0OOedO(i)/sum(j,edO(j)); inc("lab') =100*lsO/sum(hh,cO(hh)); inc('cap') =100*ksO/sum(hh,cO(hh)); inc("bop') =lOO*bopdef/sum(hh,cO(hh)); inc("gov') = lOOgovdef/sum(hh,cO(hh)); inc('inv') = lOOsum(i,-idO(i))/sum(hh,cO(hh)); option aggr:l:O:l,ecs:l:O:l,fxs:l; display aggr,vastat,ecs,tsh,fxs; * Tables for paper: policy(i, CBTO") = trd(i,"CBTO'); policy(i,"TD') = trd(i,'TD'); policy(i,"NTB") = trd(i,"NTB"); policy(i, CBTl1) = trd(i,"CBTl); policy(i, FX_Sub') = round(-lOO*alpha(i),O); policy(i,"EN_Sub") = round(-lOO*gamma(i),O); hhexp(hh,'Food') = round(lOO*sum(ess,cdO(ess,hh))/sum(i,cdO(i,hh)),2); hhexp(hh,"Energy') = round(lOO*sum(ene,cdO(ene,hh))/sum(i,cdO(i,hh)),2); hhexp(hh,'Transp") = round(lOO*sum(tsp,cdO(tsp,hh))/sum(i,cdO(i,hh)),2); hhexp(hh,'Other") = round(100-hhexp(hh,"Energy")-hhexp(hh,"Transpl)- hhexp(hh,'Food"),2); option policy:l,hhexp:O; display policy,hhexp; *.$libinclude ssexport policy policy.wkl alldat *.$libinclude ssdump hhexp hhexp.wkl display govdef, nsO,gsO; * Declare the model: $ontext $model:static $sectors: co(hh) ! Private consumption by income groups go Public sector demand y(i) Sectoral production a(i) Armington supply m(i)$mO(i) Imports ex(i)$(not cru(i)) ! Exports cex$(not exo) ! Crude oil exports $commodities: pc(hh) Consumption price urban consumers pg Public goods price pl Wage rate rk Return to capital rn(nr) Rent to natural resources pa(i) Armington price pm(i)$mO(i) Import price pd(i)$(not cru(i)) ! Domestic market price py(i) Costs of domestic production pfx Foreign exchange $consumer: ra(hh) ! Households govt ! Government dummy Dummy agent collecting NTB rents Sauxiliary: ls Lump-sum tax multiplier my(i)$fsub(i) ! Food subsidies chi(i)$gamma(i) Energy subsidy multiplier beta(i)$alpha(i) ! Subsidy to selected imports $prod:ex(i)$(not cru(i)) t:arm(i) o:pfx q:edO(i) o:pd(i) q:dO(i) i:py(i) q:(dO(i)+edO(i)) $prod:cex$(not exo) o:pfx q:(sum(cru,edO(cru))) i:py(cru) q:edO(cru) Other production: $prod:y(i)$oth(i) s:O vae:O.5 va(vae):l o:py(i) q:(dO(i)+edO(i)) a:govt t:ty(i) i:pa(j) q:ii(j,i) vae:$ene(j) i:pl q:ldO(i) va: i:rk q:kdO(i) va: * Oil refining: $prod:y(i)$(ene(i)) s:O va:l o:py(i) q:(dO(i)+edO(i)) a:govt t:ty(i) i:pa(j) q:ii(j,i) i:pl q:ldO(i) va: i:rk q:kdO(i) va: Primary production: $prod:y(nr) s:sff(nr) sa:O o:py(nr) q:(edO(nr)+dO(nr)) a:govt t:ty(nr) i:pa(j) q:ii(j,nr) sa: i:pl q:ldO(nr) sa: i:rk q:(O.5*kdO(nr)) sa: i:rn(nr) q:(O.5*kdO(nr)) $prod:a(i) s:arm(i) o:pa(i) q:aO(i) a:govt n:my(i)$fsub(i) m:(-l)$fsub(i) i:pm(i) q:mO(i) p:pmO(i) a:govt n:chi(i)$gamma(i) m:gamma(i)$gamma i) + t:tm(i) a:dummy t:((l+tm(i))*ntbO(i)) i:pd(i)$(not cru(i)) q:dO(i) p:pdO(i) a:govt n:chi(i)$gamma(i) m:gamnmna(i)$gamma i) i:py(i)$cru(i) q:dO(i) $constraint:chi(i)$gamma(i) pa(i) =g= sum(hh,incsh(hh)*pc(hh)); $demand:dummy s:O d:pl$va q:(l-kvs) d:rk$va q:kvs d:pc(hh)$(not va) q:incsh(hh) $constraint:my(i)$fsub(i) sum(hh,incsh(hh)*pc(hh)) =g= pa(i); $prod:m(i)$mO(i) s:O o:pm(i) q:mO(i) i:pfx q:qOC(i) a:govt n:beta(i)$alpha(i) m:alpha(i)$alpha(i) $constraint:beta(i)$alpha(i) sum(hh,incsh(hh)*pc(hh)) =g= pm(i); $report: v:dsup(i) i:pd(i) prod:a(i) v:msup(i) i:prm(i) prod:a(i) v:xsup(i) o:pfx prod:ex(i) v:ldem(i) i:pl prod:y(i) $prod:co(hh) s:0.4 a:l o:pc(hh) q:cO(hh) i:pa(i) q:cdO(i,hh) a:$high(i) $prod:go s:O o:pg q:gO i:pa(i) q:gdO(i) * Government agent: $demand:govt d:pg q:gO e:rk q:gsO e:rn("ext") q:nsO("ext") e:pl q:(-govdef) e:pfx q:(-l) r:ls Exogenous exports of crude oil: e:py(cru)$exo q:(-edOC(cru)) e:pfx$exo q:(sum(cru,edO(cru))) *==============================~=============================== ---------------- * Households: $demand:ra(hh) d:pc(hh) q:cO(hh) e:pl q:(lsO*incsh(hh)) e:rk q:(ksO*incsh(hh)) e:rn(nr)$(not cru(nr)) q:(nsO(nr)*incsh(hh)) e:pfx q:(bopdef*incsh(hh)) e:pl q:(cgovdef*incsh(hh)) e:pfx q:nohh(hh) r:ls e:pa(i) q:((-idO(i))*incsh(hh)) $constraint:ls go =e= 1; $offtext $sysinclude mpsgeset static * Replicate the benchmark: ls.l = 0; ls.lo = -inf; ls.up = +inf; my.lIi) = 0; chi.l(i) = 1; beta.l(i) = 1; static.iterlim = 0; $include static.gen solve static using mcp; static.iterlim - 10000; * Report parameters: scalar cpi Consumer price index, gdp Gross domestic product; gdp = sum(i,kdO(i)+ld0(i)); parameter Welfare Aggregate welfare change (% of household consumption) WelfGDP Aggregate welfare change (% of GDP) Welfhh Welfare change by household Welfnet Welfare change net of lump-sum transfer GilProd Production of crude OilExp Crude oil exports OilRef Oil refining activity EinCost Costs of domestic energy intensive production (% change) P_transp Price of transportation services Subsidy Average petroleum subsidies (%) EnePrice Energy price index (% change) OilPrice Oil price index (% change) CruPrice Domestic price of crude oil (% change) Exhrate Real exchange rate (% change) RealWage Real wage (% change) ReturnK Real return to capital OilRent Real return to oil oilSub Oil subsidies (% of GDP) FoodSub Food subsidies FxSub Foreign exchange subsidies (% of GDP) TmRev Tariff revenue (% of GDP) OilRent Oil rent (% of GDP) Fiscal Net fiscal effect (% of GDP) AvTar Average tarrif rate Exports Aggregate exports FodPrice Price of primary food FopPrice Price of processed food products SugPrice Price of sugar MedPrice Price of medicine Activ Output by sector (% change) DomCost Costs of domestic production export Exports (% change) explev Exports (levels) emplev Employment (levels) RP Rate of protection AIJ Cost share of intermediate inputs in total costs ERP Effective rate of protection * Scenario definitions and report writing: ENERGY POLICY ANALYSIS * Foreign exchange subsidies: $if %fxsubs% == "Yes" alpha(i) = 0; * Food subsidies: $if %fsub% == "Yes" fsub(ess) = 1; * Replace NTBs with tariffs: $if %ntbs% == "Tariff" ntbO(i) 0; $if %ntbs% == "Tariff" tm(i)$(not pet(i)) = trd(i,"TD+CBTl")/100; * Remove NTBs and impose a uniform tariff: $if %ntbs% == "Uniform" ntbO(i) = 0; $if %ntbs% == "Uniform" tm(i)$(not pet(i)) 0.15; * Replace NTBs with tariffs but no rates beyond 25% $if %ntbs% == "25" ntbO(i) 0; $if %ntbs% == "25" tm(i)$(not pet(i)) = min(0.25,trd(i,"TD+CBTl")/100); * Eliminate all trade distortions: $if %ntbs% == "Free" ntbO(i) = 0; $if %ntbs% "Free' tm(i) = 0; $if %ntbs% == "Free" alpha(i) = 0; * Eliminate all trade distortions, except a uniform 15% tariff: $if %ntbs% == "15" ntbO(i) = 0; $if %ntbs% == "15" tm(i)$(not pet(i)) = 0.15; $if %ntbs% == "15" alpha(i) = 0; $if %elimesub% == "Yes" gamma(i) = 0; $include static.gen solve static using mcp; cpi = sum(hh,incsh(hh)*pc.l(hh)); Welfare = 100*(sum(hh,co.1(hh)*cO(hh))/sum(hh,cO(hh))-l); WelfGDP = 100'(sum(hh,(co.l(hh)-l)*c0(hh))f/dp); Welfhh(hh) = round(l00*(co.l(hh)-l),l); Welfnet(hh) = round(l00*( (co.l(hh)*c0{hh)-pfx.l/pc.l(hh)*nohh(hh)"ls.l)/c0(hh.- 1), 1)i Exhrate = 100*(pfx.l/sum(i,pd.l(i)*dsup.l(i)/sum(j,dsup.l(j)))-1); RealWage = 100'(pl.l/cpi-1); ReturnK = 100*(rk.1/cpi-1); FxSub = 1001(sum(oe,pfx.l*m.l(oe)*qO(oe)*beta.l(oe)*alpha(oe))/cpi- govstat("fx"))/gdp; OilSub 100*(sum(pet,(pm.l(pet)*msup.l(pet)+pd.l(pet)*dsup.l(pet))*chi.l(pet)*gamma(pet))/c:,i- govstat("ensub")) / gdp; FoodSub 100*sum(ess,-a.l(ess)*pa.l(ess)*a0(ess)*my.l(ess))/(cpi*gdp); TmRev = 100*(sum(i,pm.l(i)*msup.1(i)*tm(i))/cpi-govstat(-tm")j/gdp; OilRent = 100*(rn.l(eext)*nsO)ext")/cpi-govstat("oilrent"))/gdp; Fiscal = 100*( sum(oe,pfx.l*m.l(oe)*qO(oe)*beta.l(oe)*alpha(oe))/cpi-govstat("f>:s') sum(pet,(pm.l(pet)*msup.l(pet)+pd.l(pet)*dsup.l(pet))'chi.l(pet)*gamma(pet))/cpi- govstat( ensub") + sum(i,pm.l(i)*msup.l(i)*tm(i))/cpi-govstat('tm") + sum(ess,-a.l(ess)*pa.l(ess)*aO(ess)*my.l(ess))/cpi + rn.l("ext')*nsO("ext")/cpi-govstat('oilrent") )/gdp; AvTar = 100*sum(ipm.l(i)*msup.l(i)*tm(i))/surm(i,pm.l(i)*msup.l(i)); Exports = 100*((sum(i,xsup.l(i)Y+sum(cru,edO(cru))*(li$exo+cex.l$(not exo)) / sum(i,edO(i))-l); FodPrice = 100(pa.l("frm')/cpi-l); FopPrice = 100'(pa.1('foo")/cpi-1); SugPrice = 100*(pa.l("sgr")/cpi-1); MedPrice = l00'(pa.1('pha')/cpi-1); Activ)i) = 100'(y.l)i)-l); DomCost(i) = 100*(py.l(i)/cpi-1); export(i)SedO(i) = 100*(xsup.l(i)/edO(i)-l); exportli)$cru)i)= l1OO(l$exo+cex.1$(not exo))-l); explev(i)$edO(i)= xsup.l(i)*1000000; explev(i)$cru(i)= (l$exo+cex.l$(not exo))*sumn(cru,edO(cru))*1000000; emplev(i) = ldem.l(i)*l000000; RP(i) = tm(i)+()l+tm(i))'ntb0(i)); display rp,tm; AIJ(i,j) = ii(i,j)/(dO(j)+edO(j)); ERP(i) = 100*(rp(i)-sum(j,aij (j,i)*rp)j)))/(l-sunm)j,aij(j,i))); * Install benchmark values for the government budget: $if %cgicase% == "NoChange' FxSub = l00'govstat("fx')/gdp; $if %cgicase% == 'NoChange' OilSub = 1001govstat("ensubt)/gdp; $if %cgicase% "NoChange' FoodSub = 0; $if %cgicase% == 'NoChange' TmRev = 100*govstat("tm")/gdp; $if %cgicase% == "NoChange" OilRent = l00*govstat("oilrent")/gdp; $setglobal cgisol_nd 2 $1ibinclude cgi output FxSub $1ibinclude cgi output OilSub $libinclude cgi output FoodSub $1ibinclude cgi output TmRev $libinclude cgi output OilRent $libinclude cgi output Fiscal $libinclude cgi output RealWage $libinclude cgi output ReturnK $libinclude cgi output Exhrate $1ibinclude cgi output Exports $1ibinclude cgi output AvTar $1ibinclude cgi output FodPrice $libinclude cgi output FopPrice $libinclude cgi output SugPrice $libinclude cgi output MedPrice $libinclude cgi output Welfare $libinclude cgi output Welfhh hh $libinclude cgi output welfnet hh $libinclude cgi output Activ i file dump /%cgicase%.sol/; put dump; parameter result; result("FxSub , "%cgicase%') = FxSub result("OilSub ""%cgicase%") = OilSub result("FoodSub ","%cgicase%") = FoodSub result('TmRev ","%cgicase%") = TmRev result('OilRent ',"%cgicase%-) = OilRent result('Fiscal ",-%cgicase%") = Fiscal result("RealWage-,"%cgicase%") = RealWage; result('ReturnK ",%cgicase%") = ReturnK result(-Exhrate ',"%cgicase%") = Exhrate result('AvTar ',"%cgicase%-) = AvTar result(sExports *,"%cgicase%") = Exports result("FodPrice-,"%cgicase%-) = FodPrice; result('FopPrice-,-%cgicase%") = FopPrice; result(ISugPrice,"%cgicase%") = SugPrice; result('MedPrice- "%cgicase%") = MedPrice; result ('Welfare * "%cgicase%-) = Welfare result("WelfGDP *,'%cgicase%") = WelfGDP set nhh /rnOlIrnlO,unOl*unlO/, nhhmap(hh,nhh) / rOl.rn0l,rO2.rnO2,rO3.rnO3,rO4.rnO4,rO5.rnO5,rO6.rnO6,rO7.rnO7,rO8.rnO8,rO9.rnO9,rlO.r nlO uOl.unOl,uO2.unO2,uO3.unO3,uO4.unO4,uO5.unO5,uO6.unO6,uO7.unO7,uO8.unO8,uO9.unO9,ulO.u nlO /; set alti / FRMp,LVSp,OAGp,MNGp,EXTp,SGRp,FOOp,PPPp,CMTp,BRKp,GCMp,GLSp, NMPp,TXTp,CLOp,LEAp,PLCp,PHAp,KERp,FOIp,GNEp,GILp,LQGp,OCPp, METp,CALp,MPSp,MACp,RTVp,MEQp,OIPp,ELEp,WATp,NGSp,CONp,TRDp, RNTp, HOTp,LTRp,PTRp,COMp,OTTp,OSVp/ altimap(i,alti) / FRM.FRMp,LVS.LVSp,OAG.OAGp,MNG.MNGp,EXT.EXTp,SGR.SGRp,FOO.FOOp, PPP.PPPp,CMT.CMTp,BRK.BRKp,GCM.GCMp,GLS.GLSp,NMP.NMPp,TXT.TXTp, CLO.CLOp,LEA.LEAp,PLC.PLCp,PHA.PHAp,KER.KERp,FOI.FOIp,GNE.GNEp, GIL.GILp,LQG.LQGp,OCP.OCPp,MET.METp,CAL.CALp,MPS.MPSp,MAC.MACp, RTV.RTVp,MEQ.MEQp,OIP.OIPp,ELE.ELEp,WAT.WATp,NGS.NGSp,CON.CONp, TRD.TRDp,RNT.RNTp,HOT.HOTp,LTR.LTRp,PTR.PTRp,COM.COMp,OTT.OTTp, OSV. OSVp/; set altj / FRMe,LVSe,OAGe,MNGe,EXTe,SGRe,FOe,PPPe,CMTe,BRKe,GCMee,GLSe, NMPe,TXTe,CLOe,LEAe,PLCe,PHAe,KERe,FOIe,GNEe,GILe,LQGe,OCPe, METe,CALe,MPSe,MACe,RTVe,MEQe,OIPe,ELEe,WATe,NGSe,CONe,TRDe, RNTe,HOTe,LTRe,PTRe,COMe,OTTe,OSVe/ altjmap(j,altj) / FRM.FRMe,LVS.LVSe,OAG.OAGe,MNG.MNGe,EXT.EXTe,SGR.SGRe,FOO.FOOe, PPP.PPPe,CMT.CMTe,BRK.BRKe,GCM.GCMe,GLS.GLSe,NMP.NMPe,TXT.TXTe, CLO.CLOe,LEA.LEAe,PLC.PLCe,PHA.PHAe,KER.KERe,FOI.FOIe,GNE.GNEe, GIL.GILe,LQG.LQGe,OCP.OCPe,MET.METe,CAL.CALe,MPS.MPSe,MAC.MACe, RTV.RTVe,MEQ.MEQe,OIP.OIPe,ELE.ELEe,WAT.WATe,NGS.NGSe,CON.CONe, TRD.TRDe,RNT.RNTe,HOT.HOTe,LTR.LTRe,PTR.PTRe,COM.COMe,OTT.OTTe, OSV.OSVe/; set altx / FRMx,LVSx,OAGx,MNGx,EXTx,SGRx,FOOx,PPPx,CMTx,BRKx,GCMx,GLSx, NMPx,TXTx,CLOx,LEAx,PLCx,PHAx,KERx,FOIx,GNEx,GILx,LQGx,OCPx, METx,CALx,MPSx,MACx,RTVx,MEQx,OIPx,ELEx,WATx,NGSx,CONx,TRDx, RNTX,HOTx,LTRx,PTRx,COMx,OTTx,OSVx/ altxmap(i,altx) / FRM.FRMx,LVS.LVSx,OAG.OAGx,MNG.MNGx,EXT.EXTx,SGR.SGRx,FOO.FOOx, PPP.PPPx,CMT.CMTx,BRK.BRKx,GCM.GCMx,GLS.GLSx,NMP.NMPx,TXT.TXTx, CLO.CLOx,LEA.LEAx,PLC.PLCx,PHA.PHAx,KER.KERx,FOI.FOIx,GNE.GNEx, GIL.GILx,LQG.LQGx,OCP.OCPx,MET.METx,CAL.CALx,MPS.MPSx,MAC.MACx, RTV.RTVx,MEQ.MEQx,OIP.OIPx,ELE.ELEx,WAT.WATx,NGS.NGSx,CON.CONx, TRD.TRDx,RNT.RNTx,HOT.HOTx,LTR.LTRx,PTR.PTRx,COM.COMx,OTT.OTTx, OSV. OSVx/; set altw / FRMw,LVSw,OAGw,MNGw,EXTw,SGRw,F00w,PPPw,CMTw,BRKw,GCMW,GLSw, NMPw,TXTw,CLOw,LLEAw,PLCw,PHAw,KERw,FOIw,GNEw,GILw,LQGw,OCPw, METw,CALw,MPSw,MACw,RTVw,MEQw,OIPw,ELEw,WATw,NGSw,CONw,TRDw, RNTw,HOTw,LTRw,PTRw,COMw,OTTw,OSVw/ altwmap(i,altw) / FRM.FRMw,LVS.LVSw,OAG.OAGw,MNG.MNGw,EXT.EXTw,SGR.SGRw,FOO.FOOw, PPP.PPPw,CMT.CMTw,BRK.BRKw,GCM.GCMw,GLS.GLSw,NMP.NMPw,TXT.TXTw, CLO.CLOw,LEA.LEAw,PLC.PLCw,PHA.PHAw,KER.KERw,FOI.FOIw,GNE.GNEw, GIL.GILw,LQG.LQGw,OCP.OCPw,MET.METw,CAL.CALw,MPS.MPSw,MAC.MACw, RTV.RTVw,MEQ.MEQw,OIP.OIPw,ELE.ELEw,WAT.WATw,NGS.NGSw,CON.CONw, TRD.TRDw,RNT.RNTw,HOT.HOTw,LTR.LTRw,PTR.PTRw,COM.COMw,OTT.OTTw, OSV.OSVw/; set altl / FRMl,LVSl,OAGl,MNGl,EXT1,SGR1,FOOl,PPPl,CMTl,BRKl,GCMl,GLSi, NMPl,TXTl,CLOl,LEAl,PLCl,PHAl,KERl,FOIl,GNEl,GILl,LQGl,OCPl, METl,CALl,MPSl,MACl,RTVl,MEQl,OIPl,ELE1,WAT1,NGS1,CON1,TRD1, RNTl,HOT1,LTR1,PTR1,COM1,OTTl,OSVl/ altlmap(i,altl) / FRM.FRM1,LVS.LVS1,OAG.OAG1,MNG.MNG1,EXT.EXT1,SGR.SGRl,FOO.FOOl, PPP.PPP1,CMT.CMTI,BRK.BRK1,GCM.GCM1,GLS.GLS1,NMP.NMP1,TXT.TXT1, CLO.CLOI,LEA.LEA1,PLC.PLCI,PHA.PHAI,KER.KERI,FOI.FOIl,GNE.GNEl, GIL.GILl,LQG.LQGI,OCP.OCPl,MET.MET1,CAL.CALl,MPS.MPS1,MAC.MACl, RTV.RTV1,MEQ.MEQI,OIP.OIP1,ELE.ELEl,WAT.WAT1,NGS.NGS1,CON.CON1, TRD.TR1D,RNT.RNTI,HOT.HOT1,LTR.LTRI,PTR.PTR1,COM.COM1,OTT.GTTI, OSV.OSV1/; result(hh,"%cgicase%') = welfhh(hh); '.result(nhh,"%cgicase%") = sum(nhhmap(hh,nhh),welfnet(hh)); result(i, "%cgicase%') = activ(i); result(alti, "%cgicase%") = sum(altimap(i,alti),domcost(i)); result(alti, "%cgicase%") = sum(altjmap(j,alt,) ,erp(j)); result(altx, "%cgicase%") = sum(altxmap(i,altx),export(i)); result(altl, "%cgicase%") = sum(altlmap(j,all),emplev(j)); result(altw, '%cgicase%") = sum(altwmap(i,altw),explev(i)); 5libinclude gams2txt result